Skip to main content
Log in

Non-implementability of Arrow–Debreu equilibria by continuous trading under volatility uncertainty

  • Published:
Finance and Stochastics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In diffusion models, a few suitably chosen financial securities allow to complete the market. As a consequence, the efficient allocations of static Arrow–Debreu equilibria can be attained in Radner equilibria by dynamic trading. We show that this celebrated result generically fails if there is Knightian uncertainty about volatility. A Radner equilibrium with the same efficient allocation as in an Arrow–Debreu equilibrium exists if and only if the discounted net trades of the equilibrium allocation display no ambiguity in the mean. This property is violated generically in endowments, and thus Arrow–Debreu equilibrium allocations are generically unattainable by dynamically trading a few long-lived assets.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Existence is not a trivial application of the well-known results on existence of general equilibrium for Banach lattices. Under volatility uncertainty, the natural commodity space consists of bounded and quasi-continuous functions. A mapping is quasi-continuous if it is continuous in nearly all its domain. The property of quasi-continuity comes for free in the probabilistic setting: Lusin’s theorem establishes the fact that any measurable function on a nice topological space is quasi-continuous. Under volatility uncertainty, this equivalence between measurability and quasi-continuity no longer holds true. We are thus led to study a new commodity space which has not been studied so far in general equilibrium theory. Compare also the discussion of this space in the recent contributions by Epstein and Ji [20], Vorbrink [35] and Beissner [4]. For this commodity space, the available existence theorems do not immediately apply. The abstract question of existence must thus be dealt with separately, but we leave the general question of existence for the future as it is not the main concern of this paper.

  2. Knightian uncertainty requires a reconsideration of some measure-theoretic results. Under risk, a measurable function on a nice topological space is “almost” continuous in the sense that for every \(\epsilon >0\), there is an open set \(O\) with probability at least \(1-\epsilon \) such that the function is continuous on \(O\); this is Lusin’s theorem. Under non-dominated Knightian uncertainty, this Lusin property, or quasi-continuity, does not come for free from measurability, and one needs to impose it. We refer to Epstein and Ji [20] and Denis et al. [15] for the financial and measure-theoretic background.

  3. In that case, the question of Radner implementability is much more complex and was only recently solved by Anderson and Raimondo [1], Hugonnier et al. [22], Riedel and Herzberg [29] and Kramkov [25], in different settings. If the asset market is potentially complete in the sense that sufficiently many independent dividend streams are traded, then one can obtain endogenously dynamically complete asset markets in sufficiently smooth Markovian economies. For non-smooth economies and non-Markovian state variables, the question is still open. As we focus on the limits of implementability under Knightian uncertainty, we consider the case of an exogenous asset structure as in Duffie and Huang [17]. If one cannot even implement the Arrow–Debreu equilibrium in this case, one should not expect to implement in the more complex situations either.

  4. Although this task has not been carried out formally, as far as we know.

References

  1. Anderson, R., Raimondo, R.: Equilibrium in continuous-time financial markets: endogenously dynamically complete markets. Econometrica 76, 841–907 (2008)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Anderson, R., Zame, W.R.: Genericity with infinitely many parameters. B.E. J. Theor. Econ. 1, 1–64 (2001)

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Arrow, K.J.: Le rôle des valeurs boursières pour la répartition la meilleure des risques. In: Économétrie. Colloques Internationaux du Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique (Paris 1952), vol. 40, pp. 41–47. C.N.R.S, Paris (1953). Discussion, pp. 47–48; English translation: Rev. Econ. Stud. 31, 91–96 (1964)

    Google Scholar 

  4. Beissner, P.: Microeconomic theory of financial economics under volatility uncertainty. PhD thesis, Bielefeld University (2014). Available online at https://pub.uni-bielefeld.de/publication/2681903

  5. Bewley, T.: Existence of equilibria in economies with infinitely many commodities. J. Econ. Theory 4, 514–540 (1972)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  6. Billot, A., Châteauneuf, A., Gilboa, I., Tallon, J.: Sharing beliefs: between agreeing and disagreeing. Econometrica 68, 685–694 (2000)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  7. Chen, Z., Epstein, L.G.: Ambiguity, risk and asset returns in continuous time. Econometrica 70, 1403–1443 (2002)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Dana, R.: Existence and uniqueness of equilibria when preferences are additively separable. Econometrica 61, 953–957 (1993)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  9. Dana, R.: On equilibria when agents have multiple priors. Ann. Oper. Res. 114, 105–112 (2002)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Dana, R.A., Pontier, M.: On the existence of an Arrow–Radner equilibrium in the case of complete markets. A remark. Math. Oper. Res. 17, 148–163 (1992)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Dana, R.A., Riedel, F.: Intertemporal equilibria with Knightian uncertainty. J. Econ. Theory 148, 1582–1605 (2013)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  12. Davis, M.H.A.: Complete-market models of stochastic volatility. Proc. R. Soc. A 460, 11–26 (2004)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Davis, M.H.A., Obłój, J.: Market completion using options. In: Stettner, Ł. (ed.) Advances in Mathematics of Finance. Banach Center Publications, vol. 83, pp. 49–60 (2008)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  14. de Castro, L.I., Châteauneuf, A.: Ambiguity aversion and trade. Econ. Theory 48, 243–273 (2011)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  15. Denis, L., Hu, M., Peng, S.: Function spaces and capacity related to a sublinear expectation: application to \(G\)-Brownian motion paths. Potential Anal. 34, 139–161 (2011)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  16. Duffie, D.: Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton (1992)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  17. Duffie, D., Huang, C.F.: Implementing Arrow–Debreu equilibria by continuous trading of few long-lived securities. Econometrica 53, 1337–1356 (1985)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  18. Duffie, D., Zame, W.: The consumption-based capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 57, 1274–1298 (1989)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  19. Ehling, P., Heyerdahl-Larsen, C.: Complete and incomplete financial markets in multi-good economies. J. Econ. Theory 160, 438–462 (2015)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  20. Epstein, L., Ji, S.: Ambiguous volatility and asset pricing in continuous time. Rev. Financ. Stud. 26, 1740–1786 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Heston, S.L.: A closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility with applications to bond and currency options. Rev. Financ. Stud. 6, 327–343 (1993)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  22. Hugonnier, J., Malamud, S., Trubowitz, E.: Endogenous completeness of diffusion driven equilibrium markets. Econometrica 80, 1249–1270 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  23. Hunt, B.R., Sauer, T., Prevalence, J.A.Y.: A translation–invariant ‘almost everywhere’ on infinite-dimensional spaces. Bull., New Ser., Am. Math. Soc. 27, 217–238 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J.P., Shreve, S.E.: Existence and uniqueness of multi-agent equilibrium in a stochastic, dynamic consumption/investment model. Math. Oper. Res. 15, 80–128 (1990)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  25. Kramkov, D.: Existence of an endogenously complete equilibrium driven by a diffusion. Finance Stoch. 19, 1–22 (2015)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  26. Mas-Colell, A., Zame, W.: Equilibrium theory in infinite dimensional spaces. In: Hildenbrand, W., Sonnenschein, H. (eds.) Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 4, pp. 1835–1898. Elsevier Science Publishers B.V., Amsterdam (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  27. Peng, S.: G-expectation, \(G\)-Brownian motion and related stochastic calculus of Itô type. In: Benth, F.E., et al. (eds.) Stochastic Analysis and Applications. The Abel Symposium 2005, pp. 541–567. Springer, Berlin (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  28. Peng, S.: Nonlinear expectations and stochastic calculus under uncertainty. Preprint (2010). Available online at https://arxiv.org/abs/1002.4546

  29. Riedel, F., Herzberg, F.: Existence of financial equilibria in continuous time with potentially complete markets. J. Math. Econ. 49, 398–404 (2013)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  30. Rigotti, L., Shannon, C.: Uncertainty and risk in financial markets. Econometrica 73, 203–243 (2005)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  31. Romano, M., Touzi, N.: Contingent claims and market completeness in a stochastic volatility model. Math. Finance 7, 399–412 (1997)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  32. Schwarz, D.C.: Market completion with derivative securities. Finance Stoch. 21, 263–284 (2017)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  33. Soner, H.M., Touzi, N., Zhang, J.: Martingale representation theorem for the \(G\)-expectation. In: Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, vol. 121, pp. 265–287 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  34. Tallon, J.M.: Do sunspots matter when agents are Choquet-expected-utility maximizers? J. Econ. Dyn. Control 22, 357–368 (1998)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  35. Vorbrink, J.: Financial markets with volatility uncertainty. J. Math. Econ. 53, 64–78 (2014)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  36. Žitković, G.: Financial equilibria in the semimartingale setting: complete markets and markets with withdrawal constraints. Finance Stoch. 10, 99–119 (2006)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge financial support by the German Research Foundation (DFG) via CRC 1283 “Taming Uncertainty …” and Grant Ri 1128-7-1. We thank the referees of this journal and Volker Böhm, Rose-Anne Dana, Christoph Kuzmics, Filipe Martins-da-Rocha and seminar audiences at ETH Zurich, LMU Munich, Rhein-Main-Kolloquium Frankfurt, the Byrne Workshop on Stochastic Analysis in Finance and Insurance at Michigan, D-TEA 2015, York, Paris Dauphine, the BGTS Summer School on Model Uncertainty in Finance and Economics, TU Berlin, de Finetti Seminar Milano, Shandong University and at our own universities for comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Frank Riedel.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proofs of Sect. 3

We recall basic results for expected utility economies from [8]. For weights \(\alpha ^{i} \ge 0\) and \(x>0\), denote by \(c_{\alpha }\) the maximizer of \(\sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} u ^{i}(c^{i})\) over \(\{c \in \mathbb{R}^{I}_{+}:\sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} c ^{i} = x\}\). This so-called \(\alpha \)-efficient allocation \(c_{\alpha }\) is characterized by the first-order conditions

$$ \alpha ^{i} \frac{d u^{i}}{d x} (c_{\alpha }^{i})= \alpha ^{j} \frac{d u ^{j}}{d x} (c_{\alpha }^{j}) = : \psi _{\alpha }(x) $$
(A.1)

for agents with strictly positive weights \(\alpha ^{i}, \alpha ^{j}>0\); agents \(i\) with weight \(\alpha _{i}=0\) have \(c_{\alpha }^{i}(x)=0\), of course. These equations define implicitly \(c_{\alpha }^{i}\) and \(\psi _{\alpha }\) as continuous functions of \(x>0\) (see [8] for the details).

Set \(\Delta =\{ \alpha \in \mathbb{R}^{I}_{+}: \sum _{i} \alpha _{i} =1 \}\) and denote by \(\mathbb{O}=(c_{\alpha }(e))_{\alpha \in \Delta }\) the set of efficient allocations in \(\mathcal{E}^{P}\). The definition of \(\mathbb{O}\) does not depend on the particular \(P\in {\mathcal{P}}\) as the \(\alpha \)-efficient allocations are defined pointwise.

Our strategy of proof is to pick an equilibrium in \(\mathcal{E}^{P}\) for an arbitrary \(P \in {\mathcal{P}}\) and to show that this equilibrium is an equilibrium in ℰ. In general, equilibrium allocations in \(\mathcal{E}^{P}\) are determined only \(P\)-almost surely. For ℰ, we need, however, that market clearing occurs quasi-surely. The allocations \(c_{\alpha }\) in (A.1) are defined pointwise for all \(\omega \in \varOmega \). In particular, we have \(\sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} c_{\alpha }^{i}(\omega )= e(\omega )\) for all \(\omega \), hence also quasi-surely.

Proof of Theorem 3.1

We first show that the allocations \(c_{\alpha }\in \mathbb{O}\) belong to our commodity space ℍ. From \(0 \le c_{\alpha }^{i} \le e\), we see that \(c_{\alpha }^{i}\) is quasi-surely bounded. As \(c_{\alpha }^{i}\) can be written as a continuous function of the aggregate endowment \(e\), \(c_{\alpha }^{i}\) is also quasi-continuous. Under Assumption 2.5, \(e\) is ambiguity-free; as a continuous function of \(e\), \(c_{\alpha }^{i}\) is also ambiguity-free.

Pick any \(P \in {\mathcal{P}}\). Due to our Assumption 2.3, the Assumptions (i)–(iv) in Dana [8] are satisfied. For Assumptions (i) (strict concavity and monotonicity), (ii) (twice continuous differentiability) and (iv) (Inada condition), this is immediate. For Assumption (iii), note that our Bernoulli utility functions are independent of the state \(\omega \); by concavity, they are bounded by some linear function. Hence Assumption (iii) of Dana is also satisfied. Since the endowments are bounded away from zero by Assumption 2.3, Assumption (E) in Dana [8] is also satisfied. We can thus apply Theorem 2.5 of Dana [8]: There exist an \(\alpha \in \Delta \) and an equilibrium \((\varPsi , c)\) in \(\mathcal{E}^{P}\) with \(c=c_{\alpha }\) \(P\)-a.s. and \(\varPsi (X)= E^{P}[ \psi _{\alpha }X]\) for \(X \in L^{\infty }(P)\). The state price \(\psi _{\alpha }\) is a continuous function of \(e\), and hence bounded q.s. By (A.1), \(\psi _{\alpha }\) is strictly positive. Due to Assumption 2.3, the individual endowments \(e^{i}\) are bounded away from zero quasi-surely. Hence we have \(\varPsi (e^{i})> 0\) for all \(i \in \mathbb{I}\). As a consequence, \(\alpha ^{i}>0\) since otherwise \(c_{\alpha }^{i}=0\) would be dominated by some strictly positive consumption plan (e.g. choose \(x >0\) with \(E^{P}[ \psi _{\alpha }x] = \varPsi (e^{i})\). By Assumption 2.3, \({U^{i}(x)=u^{i}(x)}>u ^{i}(0)\)).

We now claim that \((\varPsi , c)\) is an equilibrium in ℰ. Note that \(\varPsi \) is well defined on \(\mathbb{H} \subseteq L^{\infty }(P)\). Since \(\sum _{i \in \mathbb{I}} c_{\alpha }^{i} (\omega ) = e(\omega )\) for all \(\omega \), \(c_{\alpha }\) clears the market for every \(\omega \in \varOmega \), hence quasi-surely. The budget constraint \(\varPsi (c^{i})=\varPsi (e^{i})\) is satisfied because \((\varPsi , c)\) is an Arrow–Debreu equilibrium in \(\mathcal{E}^{P}\). It remains to show that \(c^{i}_{\alpha }\) maximizes utility in ℰ subject to the budget constraint. Let \(b\) be budget-feasible for agent \(i\). As \(c_{\alpha }\) is an Arrow–Debreu equilibrium in the expected utility economy \(\mathcal{E}^{P}\), we have \(E^{P}[ u^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i})] \ge E^{P} [u^{i}(b)]\). As \(c_{\alpha }^{i}\) is ambiguity-free, we have \(U^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i})=E^{P} [u^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i})]\). Therefore,

$$ U^{i}(b) \le E^{P} [u^{i}(b)] \le E^{P} [u^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i})] = U ^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i}). $$

 □

As a preparation for the proof of Theorem 3.2, we now show that the allocations in \(\mathbb{O}\) are also efficient in the Knightian economy ℰ. This is not obvious as in general, different measures in \(\mathcal{P}\) could be the “worst case” measure for different agents, and efficient allocations would thus depend on those worst-case measures. Our result hinges on Assumption 2.5.

Proposition A.1

1. Under Assumption 2.5, the efficient allocations in the Knightian economycoincide with the allocations in \(\mathbb{ O} =(c_{\alpha })_{\alpha \in \Delta } \). Each \(c_{\alpha }\) is ambiguity-free.

2. Under Assumption 2.6, each \(c_{\alpha }\) is full insurance.

Proof

Let \(b\in \mathbb{O}\) be an efficient allocation. It is well known that \(b\) maximizes the weighted sum of utilities \(\sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} U^{i}(b^{i}) \) for some \(\alpha \in \Delta \); compare [8, Proposition 2.3]. Set \(\varGamma = \{ \omega \in \varOmega : \exists i \in \mathbb{I}\mbox{ with }b^{i}(\omega ) \neq c^{i} _{\alpha }(\omega )\}\). As the Bernoulli utility functions \(u^{i}\) are strictly concave by Assumption 2.3 and by the definition of \(c_{\alpha }\), we have

$$ \sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} u^{i}\big(b^{i}(\omega )\big) < \sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} u^{i}\big(c_{\alpha }^{i}(\omega ) \big) $$

for all \(\omega \in \varGamma \). If \(\varGamma \) is not a polar set, there is \(P \in {\mathcal{P}}\) with \(P[\varGamma ]>0\) and we have

$$ E^{P}\bigg[ \sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} u^{i}(b^{i})\bigg] < E ^{P} \bigg[\sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} u^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i}) \bigg] . $$

Since \(c_{\alpha }\) is ambiguity-free, \(E^{P}[ \sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} u^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i})] = \sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} U^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i})\). On the other hand, by ambiguity aversion,

$$ \sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} U^{i}(c_{\alpha }^{i})\le E^{P} \bigg[\sum _{i\in \mathbb{I}} \alpha ^{i} u^{i}(b^{i})\bigg], $$

and we obtain a contradiction. We thus conclude that \(\varGamma \) is a polar set and therefore \(b=c_{\alpha }\) quasi-surely.

From Proposition 2.2 of Dana [8] (see also the discussion above), we know that \(c_{\alpha }\) is a continuous function of the aggregate endowment \(e\). Under Assumption 2.5, \(c_{\alpha }\) is thus ambiguity-free, and under Assumption 2.6, \(c_{\alpha }\) is quasi-surely constant, or full insurance. □

Proof of Theorem 3.2

Let \((\varPsi , c)\) be an Arrow–Debreu equilibrium of ℰ. By the first welfare theorem, \(c\) is efficient. By Proposition A.1, there exists \(\alpha \in \Delta \) with \(c=c_{\alpha }\) and \(c_{\alpha }\) is ambiguity-free. This proves part 1 (a). If we impose even Assumption 2.6, Proposition A.1 shows that \(c_{\alpha }\) is full insurance, proving part 2 (a).

For part 1 (b), note that we have \(\alpha ^{i}>0\) for all \(i \in \mathbb{I}\), as individual endowments are strictly positive. Otherwise, \(c^{i}_{\alpha }=0\) which is dominated by the strictly positive individual endowment \(e^{i}\) (Assumption 2.3). Due to the first order condition of individual utility maximization, any equilibrium price functional \(\varPsi \) is collinear with some supergradient of \(U^{i}\) at \(c^{i}_{\alpha }\). For any \(i\in \mathbb{I}\), the set of supergradients contains all linear functionals of the form \(\frac{d }{d x} u^{i}(c^{i}_{\alpha })\cdot P\), where \(P\) is a minimizer in the set of priors. Since \(u^{i}(c^{i}_{\alpha })\) is ambiguity-free, \(E^{P}[u^{i}(c^{i}_{\alpha })] \) is constant on \(\mathcal{P}\), and hence every element in \(\mathcal{P}\) is a minimizer of the multiple prior expected utility. From (A.1), \(\alpha ^{i}\frac{d }{d x} u^{i}(c^{i}_{\alpha })=\psi _{\alpha }\), which is independent of \(i\) and ambiguity-free by part 1 (a).

By Assumption 2.3, the marginal utilities \(\frac{d }{d x} u^{i}\) are continuous and decreasing. Since \(c_{\alpha }\) is a continuous function of the aggregate endowment \(e\) and since \(e\) is bounded away from zero, \(\psi _{\alpha }\) is quasi-continuous and bounded. Since \(e\) is also bounded and the marginal utilities \(\frac{d }{d x} u^{i}\) are decreasing, \(\psi _{\alpha }\) is also bounded away from zero. We thus obtain a price functional of the form

$$ \varPsi (b)=E^{P}[\psi _{\alpha }b] $$

such that \((c,\varPsi )\) is an Arrow–Debreu equilibrium.

For part 2 (b), note that \(\psi _{\alpha }\) is constant since \(c_{\alpha }\) is full insurance. Hence, without loss of generality, we can replace the price functional \(\varPsi (b)=E^{P} [\psi _{ \alpha } b]\) by \(\varPsi (b)=E^{P}[b]\). □

Appendix B: Beyond the Bachelier model

The Bachelier model we presented allows negative values of the price process. Theorem 4.2 is still valid when our \(G\)-Brownian motion \(B=B^{+} +B^{-}\) of the Bachelier model is decomposed into the positive part \(B^{+}\) and negative part \(B^{-}\). The trading strategies are then given by \(\theta ^{k,+}_{t}=\theta ^{k}_{t}1_{\{B^{k}_{t} \geq 0\}}\) and \(\theta ^{k,-}_{t}= -\theta ^{k}_{t}1_{\{B^{k}_{t}< 0\}}\), where \(\theta ^{k}\) denotes the fractions invested in the \(k\)th uncertain assets of Theorem 4.2. In the same fashion, as mentioned in Sect. 5 of Duffie and Huang [17], the number of assets becomes \(2 d +1\).

Theorem 4.2 is still valid if we replace the process \(B\) with a symmetric \(\mathbb{E}\)-martingale of the form \(M=M_{0}+ \int _{0}^{\cdot }V_{t} \mathrm{d}B_{t}\) such that \(V_{t} \in \mathbb{H}^{d\times d}_{+}\) with \(V^{ij}_{t}=0\) and \(V^{ii}\) is q.s. bounded away from zero. Indeed, it suffices to show that every stochastic integral of the form \(\int _{0}^{T} \theta _{s} \mathrm{d}B_{s} \) for some \(\theta \in \mathcal{M}\) can be written as \(\int _{0}^{T} \theta _{s} \mathrm{d} B_{s}=\int _{0}^{T} \theta ^{M}_{s} \mathrm{d}M_{s}\) for some suitable \(\theta ^{M}\in \mathcal{M}\). The proof then follows the same lines as the proof of Theorem 4.2, by substituting \(B\) with \(M\). The obvious candidate is \(\theta ^{M,k}_{t}= \theta ^{k}_{t} / V^{kk}_{t}\). We need to show that the stochastic integral \(\int _{0}^{T} \theta ^{M}_{t} dM _{t}\) is well defined. Note that \(\theta ^{M}\in \mathcal{M}\) because \(V^{kk}\) is bounded away from zero q.s.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Beissner, P., Riedel, F. Non-implementability of Arrow–Debreu equilibria by continuous trading under volatility uncertainty. Finance Stoch 22, 603–620 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-018-0362-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-018-0362-x

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification (2010)

JEL Classification

Navigation