Skip to main content
Log in

Tasks, technology, and factor prices in the neoclassical production sector

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper introduces tasks into the neoclassical production sector. Competitive firms choose the profit-maximizing amounts of factor-specific tasks that determine their factor demands and output supplies. We show that the effect of factor-augmenting technical change on relative and absolute factor prices can be decomposed into a productivity effect and a task-demand effect of opposite sign. These effects appear since the novel task-based approach distinguishes between the demands for tasks and the demands for factors. This perspective provides a new intuition for the emergence of relative and absolute factor biases and the role of the elasticity of substitution.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The labels “capital” and “labor” are just for convenience. Mathematically, these two factors may represent any pair of distinguishable inputs. Mutatis mutandis, the analytical setup developed here extends readily to more than two inputs each with a corresponding task type. For instance, one may want to replace the single type of tasks performed by labor with two distinct types, one performed by skilled, the other be unskilled labor.

  2. To include the CES production function, we dispense with Inada conditions. However, throughout I assume that the \(\lim _{M(i)\rightarrow 0}\partial F\left( M(i),N(i)\right) /\partial M(i)\) and \(\lim _{N(i)\rightarrow 0}\partial F\left( M(i),N(i)\right) /\partial N(i)\) are sufficiently high to deliver an interior solution to the profit-maximization problem of firms.

  3. See, e.g., Varian (1992), Chapter 1, for a traditional textbook treatment of “activity analysis.” In my analytical framework a firm’s input requirement set comprises all vectors of tasks that allow for the production of a given amount of output. Therefore, I refer to this set as the task input requirement set.

  4. Little would change in Proposition 1 and its proof if we replaced the production function of (2.1) by any homothetic function \({\tilde{F}}:{\mathbb {R}}_+^2\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}_+\) where \({\tilde{F}}\left( M(i),N(i)\right) =h\left( F\left( M(i),N(i)\right) \right) \) with \(h'\left( \cdot \right)>0>h''\left( \cdot \right) \). In fact, the equilibrium allocation and equilibrium factor price are simply obtained by replacing F by \({\tilde{F}}\).

  5. All results of Sect. 3.2.1 go through if we allow for decreasing returns to scale and replace the CES of (3.4) by \({\tilde{F}}\left( M,N\right) =\left[ F\left( M,N\right) \right] ^\nu \), where \(0<\nu <1\). Since \({\tilde{F}}\left( M,N\right) \) is homothetic, Proposition 1 continues to hold (see, Footnote 4).

  6. See Irmen (2014) for an analysis of the effect of factor-augmenting technical change on factor prices in the canonical neoclassical production sector.

  7. With slight modifications, the results of Sect. 3.2.2 go through under decreasing returns to scale as suggested in Footnote 5. As to the sign of \(dR^*/db\), we have to replace \(\gamma \) on the right hand side of (3.16) by \({\tilde{\gamma }}\equiv \nu \gamma \). The sign of \(dR^*/da\) in (3.15) is preserved as long as \(\sigma <1/(1-\nu )\).

  8. Observe that \(F\left( \ln (1+\delta bK),\ln (1+\delta a L)\right) /\delta \) is not homothetic in (bKaL). Therefore, the findings on technical change and factor prices are quite different from and have different intuitions than those stated in the Footnotes 4 - 7 for a CES with decreasing returns to efficient factor supplies.

  9. Notice that the ‘number’ of firms will affect aggregate output and factor prices since capital and labor exhibit diminishing returns in the accomplishment of tasks. A larger number of firms implies that each firm operates at a smaller scale. The equilibrium productivity of capital and labor will then be higher and aggregate output increases. In what follows we neglect this complication to facilitate the comparison with the results derived in Sect. 3.

  10. Observe that \(d\ln (R/w)/d\ln (b/a)=d\ln (R/w)/d\ln b=-d\ln (R/w)/d\ln a\) since \(d\ln (b/a)=d\ln b-d\ln a\). Therefore, the rule stated in (3.13) also applies to \(d\ln (R/w)/d\ln b\) and with opposite sign to \(d\ln (R/w)/d\ln a\).

References

  • Acemoglu D (2007) Equilibrium bias of technology. Econometrica 75(5):1371–1410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D (2009) Introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D (2010) When does labor scarcity encourage innovation? J Polit Econ 118(6):1037–1078

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Autor D (2011) Skills, tasks and technologies: implications for employment and earnings. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 4. Elevier, Amsterdam, p 1043

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Restrepo P (2018a) Artificial intelligence, automation, and work. In: Economics of artificial intelligence. NBER Chapters. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc

  • Acemoglu D, Restrepo P (2018b) The race between man and machine: implications of technology for growth, factor shares, and employment. Am Econ Rev 108(6):1488–1542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Zilibotti F (2001) Productivity differences. Q J Econ 116(2):563–606

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Champernowne DG (1961) A dynamic growth model involving a production function. In: Lutz FA, Hague DC (eds) The theory of capital—proceedings of a conference held by the international economic association. MacMillian, London (Reprinted 1963), pp 223–244

  • Dornbusch R, Fischer S, Samuelson PA (1980) Heckscher–Ohlin trade theory with a continuum of goods. Quart J Econ 95(2):203–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irmen A (2014) Real factor prices and factor-augmenting technical change. B.E. J Macroecon 14(1):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irmen A (2017) Capital- and labor-saving technical change in an aging economy. Int Econ Rev 58(1):261–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irmen A (2018) Tasks, technology, and factor prices in the neoclassical production sector. In: CREA discussion paper series 18–22. Center for Research in Economic Analysis, University of Luxembourg

  • Irmen A (2020a) Automation, growth, an factor shares in the era of population aging. In: CREA discussion paper series 20–15. Center for Research in Economic Analysis, University of Luxembourg

  • Irmen A (2020b) Endogenous task-based technical change - factor scarcity and factor prices. In: CESifo working paper series 8215, CESifo Group Munich

  • Irmen A, Tabaković A (2017) Endogenous capital- and labor-augmenting technical change in the neoclassical growth model. J Econ Theory 170:346–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (1992) Microeconomic analysis, 3rd edn. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeira J (1998) Workers, machines, and economic growth. Quart J Econ 113(4):1091–1117

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This is a revised version of my discussion paper Irmen (2018). I gratefully acknowledge financial assistance under the Inter Mobility Program of the FNR Luxembourg (“Competitive Growth Theory - CGT”). A part of this research was written while I was visiting Brown University in the Spring 2018. I would like to express my gratitude to Brown’s Economics Department for its kind hospitality. Moreover, I would like to thank Oded Galor, Ka-Kit Iong, two anonymous referees, and the editor for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andreas Irmen.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: Proofs

Appendix: Proofs

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Consider firm i’s demand for capital. With (2.5), we have \(K(i)=M(i)/b\). Hence, for \(R>0\), (2.6) delivers \(\int _0^1 K(i)di=\int _0^1 M(i)/b=K\). Hence, \(\int _0^1 M(i)di=bK=M^*\). Similarly, one derives for labor and \(w>0\) that \(\int _0^1 N(i)di=aL=N^*\). Next consider the first-order conditions (3.2). Since the derivatives \(\partial F\left( M(i),N(i)\right) /\partial M(i)\) and \(\partial F\left( M(i),N(i)\right) /\partial N(i)\) are homogeneous of degree zero, these conditions imply \(M(i)/N(i)=M(i')/N(i')\) for all \(i,i'\in [0,1]\) and \(i\ne i'\). Therefore, it holds that \(M(i)/N(i)=\left[ M(i)+M(i')\right] /\left[ N(i)+N(i')\right] \) and

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \frac{M(i)}{N(i)}\right) ^*=\frac{\int _0^1 M(i)di}{\int _0^1 N(i)di}=\frac{bK}{aL}=\frac{M^*}{N^*}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.1)

Accordingly, the equilibrium task intensity, the aggregate equilibrium output, and the equilibrium factor prices are as stated in Proposition 1. Since \(M^*\) and \(N^*\) are positive and finite, we have \(R^*>0\) and \(w^*>0\). Since \(\pi (i)\) is homogenous of degree one in \(\left( M(i),N(i)\right) \), the absolute levels \(M^*(i)\) and \(N(i)^*\) remain indeterminate. \(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

In equilibrium (3.6) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \ln \left( \frac{R^*}{w^*}\right) =\ln \gamma +\ln \left( \frac{b}{a}\right) - \frac{1}{\sigma }\ln \left( \frac{M^*}{N^*}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

In light of (3.8) the proposition follows. \(\square \)

1.3 Proof of Proposition 3

We start proving that \(M(i)=M(j)=M^*\) and \(N(i)=N(j)=N^*\) for all \(i,j\in [0,1]\) and \(i\ne j\) holds in equilibrium. Since \(C(i)=C\left( M(i),N(i)\right) \) is strictly convex, profits \(\pi (i)=\pi \left( M(i),N(i)\right) \) are strictly concave. Assume to the contrary that two firms i and j choose \(\left( M(i),N(i)\right) \ne \left( M(j),N(j)\right) \). This is only possible if \(\pi \left( M(i),N(i)\right) =\pi \left( M(j),N(j)\right) \). Now, consider \(\left( M,N\right) =\mu \left( M(i),N(i)\right) +(1-\mu )\left( M(j),N(j)\right) \) for some \(\mu \in (0,1)\). Since profits are strictly concave we have \(\pi \left( M,N\right) >\mu \pi \left( M(i),N(i)\right) +(1-\mu )\pi \left( M(j),N(j)\right) \). Therefore, \(\pi \left( M,N\right) >\pi \left( M(i),N(i)\right) =\pi \left( M(j),N(j)\right) \) which is a contradiction. Hence, for all \(i\in [0,1]\) we must have \(\left( M(i),N(i)\right) =\left( M,N\right) \).

As a consequence, the aggregate demand for capital of all firms is \(\int _0^M e^{\delta m}dm/b=\left( e^{\delta M}-1\right) /(\delta b)\). Hence, for \(R>0\), (2.6) delivers \(M^*\) as indicated in the proposition. Similarly, one derives \(N^*\). The first-order conditions (4.2) deliver \(R^*\) and \(w^*\) as indicated. Since \(F(\cdot )\) has constant returns to scale, \(F\left( M^*,N^*\right) =F\left( \ln (1+\delta bK),\ln (1+\delta a L)\right) /\delta \). \(\square \)

1.4 Proof of Proposition 4

The statements of Eq. (4.6) are immediate from (4.5). Computing the respective effects delivers with \(z\equiv \delta b K\)

$$\begin{aligned} \delta M^* \frac{\partial \ln M^*}{\partial \ln b}=\frac{z}{1+z}\quad \text{ and }\quad \frac{1}{\sigma }\frac{\partial \ln M^*}{\partial \ln b}=\frac{1}{\sigma }\left( \frac{z}{1+z}\right) \left( \frac{1}{\ln (1+z)}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(6.2)

It follows that \({\bar{\sigma }}_b=z/(\ln (1+z))>1\) which is increasing in z, hence, also in \(\delta \). As to labor, let \(x\equiv \delta a L\). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} \delta N^* \frac{\partial \ln N^*}{\partial \ln a}=\frac{x}{1+x}\quad \text{ and }\quad \frac{1}{\sigma }\frac{\partial \ln N^*}{\partial \ln a}=\frac{1}{\sigma }\left( \frac{x}{1+x}\right) \left( \frac{1}{\ln (1+x)}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(6.3)

It follows that \({\bar{\sigma }}_a=x/(\ln (1+x))>1\) which is increasing in x, hence, also in \(\delta \). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Irmen, A. Tasks, technology, and factor prices in the neoclassical production sector. J Econ 131, 101–121 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00705-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00705-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation