Skip to main content
Log in

A Model of Secular Migration from Centralized to Decentralized Trade

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A large number of financial assets are traded in both exchanges and over-the-counter markets (i.e., centralized and decentralized markets, CM and DM hereafter, respectively). Moreover, as documented by Biais and Green (Rev Econ Dyn 33:250–271, 2019), the twentieth century has witnessed a secular migration of asset trade from CM to DM. To this end, this paper develops a tractable model on strategic selection of venue trading to study the causes and consequences of the endogenous coexistence of CM and DM. In the model, traders’ choice of venue is shaped by the trade-off between information frictions in the CM and matching frictions in the DM. Closed-form solutions are obtained and used to characterize the endogenous share of trade across the two venues. We then use the model to evaluate two potential explanations of the migration from CM to DM: improvements in matching technologies and increases in the number of institutional investors. Surprisingly, while both forces could lead to more trade in DM, there exist parameter regions where the increase in the number of institutional investors leads to less trade in DM. We also obtain empirically testable implications that differentiate the two explanations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Quantitatively, equities are largely traded on exchanges right now, while US Treasuries are mostly traded in over-the-counter markets. Additionally, see Hasbrouck (2007) and O’hara (1995) for a comprehensive survey of market structure and Harris (2003) for the details of the coexistence of exchange and OTC markets.

  2. The first version of the paper by Biais and Green 2007, and the paper was published in 2019. Therefore, we cited both Biais and Green (2007) and Biais and Green (2019).

  3. See Duffie et al. (2005), Lagos and Rocheteau (2009), Hugonnier et al. (2014), Atkeson et al. (2015) and Zhang (2018), among others, for the analysis of OTC markets. See Duffie (2011) for a survey.

  4. See Dong et al. (2016) for the effect of search frictions in the credit markets on equilibrium indeterminacy, which then translates into endogenous credit cycles.

  5. In Sect. 2, we will fully characterize three alternative cases, in which either of them is private information and both of them are private information. Meanwhile, see Geromichalos and Herrenbrueck (2016), among others, for the microfoundation of the liquidity shock.

  6. We thank a referee for this point.

  7. Bolton et al. (2011) discuss the endogenous choice between financial service and real business.

  8. See Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2008) for the details on market and funding liquidity.

  9. Some asset trading is dealer-intermediated in our real life, with corporate bonds just being a case. We assume away the intermediation in this paper. It contributes to great tractability for our focus on equilibrium choice. In contrast, an oversimplified interpretation is that we combine the roles of dealers and buyers and are exclusively engaged in the trading frictions due to private information on heterogeneity of the seller side. The price of assuming way dealers in DM is that there is no room to use our model to discuss the bid-ask spread and other important dealer-related financial phenomena.

  10. We also consider an alternative scenario in which DM and CM are connected. That is, sellers have no commitment and are allowed to put their order in both markets. If sellers are not matched in DM, they still have the opportunity to liquidate their assets in CM if they want to. Most of the qualitative conclusions in the context still hold.

  11. We use random search to characterize frictions in DM throughout the paper. As shown in Online Appendix, the main results are well preserved if we consider directed search.

  12. This pricing function can be micro-founded with monopoly selling assets facing a linear demand schedule. Our result extends to other formulations of the price impact cost, such as an isoelastic demand curve. We adopt this formulation because it yields a closed-form solution and hence analytical tractability.

  13. The result regarding high equilibrium is available upon request.

  14. We thank a referee for pointing this out.

  15. All the main results will be well preserved under Cobb–Douglas matching function, but the Leontief matching technology greatly simplifies the algebra in the case of continuum liquidity shocks.

  16. In the extreme case, we could assume that the matching probability in CM is 1. The result is qualitatively the same.

  17. As shown in the end of this reply, we also characterize the other cases in which informed CM would be dominated by DM, or vice versa.

  18. Our paper is also related to a recently minted working paper by Wang (2019). Based on Geromichalos and Herrenbrueck (2016), Wang (2019) considers the sequential trade in frictional asset market, goods market and centralized markets. The key difference is that we consider endogenous coexistence of centralized and decentralized markets while Wang (2009) focuses on the sequential trade in CM and DM, as in Lagos and Wright (2005) and Geromichalos and Herrenbrueck (2016).

References

  • Akerlof, G.A.: The market for lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q. J. Econ. 84(3), 488–500 (1970)

    Google Scholar 

  • Andolfatto, D., Berentsen, A., Waller, C.: Optimal disclosure policy and undue diligence. J. Econ. Theory 149, 128–152 (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkeson, A.G., Eisfeldt, A.L., Weill, P.O.: Entry and exit in OTC derivatives markets. Econometrica 83(6), 2231–2292 (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Dong, F., Wang, P.: Adverse selection and self-fulfilling business cycles. J. Monet. Econ. 94, 114–130 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  • Biais, B., Green, R.: The microstructure of the bond market in the 20th century. Tepper School of Business, p. 134 (2007)

  • Biais, B., Green, R.: The microstructure of the bond market in the 20th century. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 33, 250–271 (2019)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bigio, S.: Endogenous liquidity and the business cycle. Am. Econ. Rev. 105(6), 1883–1927 (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., Santos, T., Scheinkman, J.A.: Outside and inside liquidity. Q. J. Econ. 126(1), 259–321 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., Santos, T., Scheinkman, J.A.: Cream-skimming in financial markets. J. Finance 71(2), 709–736 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M.K., Pedersen, L.H.: Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Rev. Financ. Stud. 22(6), 2201–2238 (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, B.: Adverse selection and liquidity distortion. Rev. Econ. Stud. 85(1), 275–306 (2017)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, J., Koeppl, T.V.: Trading dynamics with adverse selection and search: market freeze, intervention and recovery. Rev. Econ. Stud. 83(3), 969–1000 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dang, T.V., Gorton, G., Holmström, B.: Financial crises and the optimality of debt for liquidity provision. Unpublished working paper. Yale School of Management (2010)

  • DeMarzo, P., Duffie, D.: A liquidity‐based model of security design. Econometrica 67(1), 65–99 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D.W., Dybvig, P.H.: Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. J. Polit. Econ. 91(3), 401–419 (1983)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dong, F., Miao, J., Wang, P.: The perils of credit booms. Econ. Theory 66(4), 819–861 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dong, F., Wang, P., Wen, Y.: Credit search and credit cycles. Econ. Theory 61(2), 215–239 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D., Gârleanu, N., Pedersen, L.H.: Over-the-counter markets. Econometrica 73(6), 1815–1847 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D.: Dark Markets: Asset Pricing and Information Transmission in Over-the-Counter Markets. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisfeldt, A.L.: Endogenous liquidity in asset markets. J. Finance 59(1), 1–30 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Farhi, E., Tirole, J.: Liquid bundles. J. Econ. Theory 158, 634–655 (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  • Geromichalos, A., Herrenbrueck, L.: Monetary policy, asset prices, and liquidity in over-the-counter markets. J. Money Credit Bank. 48(1), 35–79 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Glosten, L.R., Milgrom, P.R.: Bid, ask and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders. J. Financ. Econ. 14(1), 71–100 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrieri, V., Shimer, R., Wright, R.: Adverse selection in competitive search equilibrium. Econometrica 78(6), 1823–1862 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrieri, V., Shimer, R.: Dynamic adverse selection: a theory of illiquidity, fire sales, and flight to quality. Am. Econ. Rev. 104(7), 1875–1908 (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrieri, V., Shimer, R.: Markets with multidimensional private information. Am. Econ. J.l: Microecon. 10(2), 250–74 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck, J.: Empirical Market Microstructure: The Institutions, Economics, and Econometrics of Securities Trading. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rust, J., Hall, G.: Middlemen versus market makers: a theory of competitive exchange. J. Polit. Econ. 111(2), 353–403 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, L.: Trading and Exchanges: Market Microstructure for Practitioners. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hugonnier, J., Lester, B., Weill, P.O.: Heterogeneity in decentralized asset markets (No. w20746). National Bureau of Economic Research (2014)

  • Ikeda, D., Phan, T.: Toxic asset bubbles. Econ. Theory 61(2), 241–271 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jullien, B.: Participation constraints in adverse selection models. J. Econ. Theory 93(1), 1–47 (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, K.: Endogenous market segmentation for lemons. Rand J. Econ. 43(3), 562–576 (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurlat, P.: Lemons markets and the transmission of aggregate shocks. Am. Econ. Rev. 103(4), 1463–1489 (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kyle, A.S.: Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 1315–1335 (1985)

  • Lagos, R., Rocheteau, G.: Liquidity in asset markets with search frictions. Econometrica 77(2), 403–426 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lagos, R., Wright, R.: A unified framework for monetary theory and policy analysis. J. Polit. Econ. 113(3), 463–484 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lester, B., Postlewaite, A., Wright, R.: Information, liquidity, asset prices, and monetary policy. Rev. Econ. Stud. 79(3), 1209–1238 (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lester, B., Shourideh, A., Venkateswaran, V., Zetlin-Jones, A.: Screening and adverse selection in frictional markets. J. Polit. Econ. 127(1), 338–377 (2019)

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R.: Finance and growth: theory and evidence. Handb. Econ. Growth 1, 865–934 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, T.R., Sappington, D.E.: Countervailing incentives in agency problems. J. Econ. Theory 49(2), 294–313 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Maggi, G., Rodriguez-Clare, A.: On countervailing incentives. J. Econ. Theory 66(1), 238–263 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Malherbe, F.: Self-fulfilling liquidity dry-ups. J. Finance 69(2), 947–970 (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  • Miao, J.: A search model of centralized and decentralized trade. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 9(1), 68–92 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • O’hara, M.: Market Microstructure Theory, vol. 108. Blackwell, Cambridge (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pagnotta, E.S., Philippon, T.: Competing on speed. Econometrica 86(3), 1067–1115 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J.: Overcoming adverse selection: how public intervention can restore market functioning. Am. Econ. Rev. 102(1), 29–59 (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Z.: Liquidity and Private Information in Asset Markets: To Signal or Not to Signal. Available at SSRN 3400267 (2019)

  • Williamson, S., Wright, R.: Barter and monetary exchange under private information. Am. Econ. Rev. 84, 104–123 (1994)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, S.: Liquidity misallocation in an over-the-counter market. J. Econ. Theory 174, 16–56 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Feng Dong.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The paper is built off the Second Chapter of the PhD dissertation by Feng Dong at Washington University in St. Louis. It was previously circulated with the title “Adverse Selection, Search Frictions and Endogenous Market Structure.” The authors list their names alphabetically. We thank the editor, the associate editor, two anonymous referees, Costas Azariadis, Mariagiovanna Baccara, Boyan Jovanovic, Albert Menkveld, Emiliano Pagnotta, B. Ravikumar, Maher Said, Chris Waller, Pengfei Wang, Yi Wen, Stephen Williamson, Russell Tsz-Nga Wong, Liyan Yang, Bart Z. Yueshen, Yao Zeng, and Junyuan Zou, along with seminar participants at Washington University in St. Louis and VU Amsterdam for helpful discussions and comments. Feng Dong acknowledges the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (#71903126) and Tsinghua University Initiative Scientific Research Program (#2019THZWJC15). The usual disclaim applies.

Appendices

Appendix

Proofs

Proof of Proposition 1 and 2:

Substituting \(c_{1}\) and \(c_{2}\) into the objective function yields

$$\begin{aligned} U^{S}\left( x,\delta \right)= & {} \underset{a\in \{0,1\}}{\max }\left\{ \max \,\left\{ \frac{m\left( b,s\right) }{s}\eta x,\,p(x)\right\} a+\delta \left[ a\mathbf {1}_{\left\{ \frac{m\left( b,s\right) }{s}\eta x>p(x)\right\} }\left( 1-\frac{m\left( b,s\right) }{s}\right) x+\left( 1-a\right) x\right] \right\} \\= & {} {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \underset{a\in \{0,1\}}{\max }\left\{ \max \,\left\{ \frac{m\left( b,s\right) }{s}\eta x,\,p(x)\right\} a\right\} , &{} \delta =0 \\ \underset{a\in \{0,1\}}{\max }\left\{ \max \,\left\{ \frac{m\left( b,s\right) }{s}\eta x,\,p(x)\right\} a+a\mathbf {1}_{\left\{ \frac{m\left( b,s\right) }{s}\cdot \eta x>p(x)\right\} }\left( 1-\frac{m\left( b,s\right) }{s}\right) x+\left( 1-a\right) x\right\} , &{} \delta =1 \end{array}\right. } . \end{aligned}$$

As a result, when \(\delta =0\), \(a^{*}=1\), i.e., investors with preference shock have to sell the claim of their projects. Investors with \(\delta =1\), however, could either participate in centralized or decentralized market (\(a=1\)) or simply wait till \(t=2\) (\(a=0\)). However, the above optimization implies that investors would never try centralized market due to search friction and bargaining.

First of all, competitive buyers set \(p(x)=x\) in complete information. In this scenario, \(p(x)>\frac{m(b,s)}{s}\eta x\) for all sellers-\((x,\delta =0)\) and thus they trade in centralized market. Moreover, sellers-\((x,\delta =1)\) would be indifferent between selling in centralized market at \(t=1\) and waiting till \(t=2\).

Secondly, in the presence of information asymmetry, \(p(x)=p\) for all sellers pooling in centralized market. On one hand, for sellers with \(\delta =0\), if decentralized market does not exist, their only choice is the centralized market. If the decentralized market exists, however, they would compare \(\frac{m(b,s)}{s}\eta x\) with p. Furthermore, if \(\frac{m(b,s)}{s} \eta x_{1}>p\), we would also have \(\frac{m(b,s)}{s}\eta x_{2}>p\) provided \(x_{2}>x_{1}\). Thus there may exist a cut-off point \(\widetilde{x}\) on the choice of trading venues. If \(\widetilde{x}\in (x_{L},x_{H})\), then \(\frac{ m(b,s)}{s}\eta \widetilde{x}=p\) holds by definition. On the other hand, for sellers with \(\delta =1\), as argued above, they would never consider trading in decentralized market even though it would be available. Instead, they simply compare p and x. As a result, those with \(x<p\) would sell their asset claims in the centralized market at \(t=1\) while those with \(x\ge p\) would enter either markets and wait till \(t=2\).

Finally, based the above two pieces of observation, we have

$$\begin{aligned} U^{s}\left( x,\delta \right)= & {} {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} p &{} if\,\,\delta =0\,\,and\,\,x\le \widetilde{x} \\ \frac{x}{\widetilde{x}}\cdot p &{} if\,\,\delta =0\,\,and\,\,x>\widetilde{x} \\ p &{} if\,\,\delta =1\,\,and\,\,x\le p \\ x &{} if\,\,\delta =0\,\,and\,\,x\le \widetilde{x} \end{array}\right. } \\= & {} \max \left\{ \frac{x}{p+\left( \widetilde{x}-p\right) \cdot \mathbf {1} _{\{\delta =0\}}},\,\,1\right\} \cdot p \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Corollary 1:

It is immediately obtained by using Proposition 1 and 2. \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 1:

The results in the general case in proved as below.

First of all, we show that \(p\le \widetilde{x}\). Eq. (3) suggests that

$$\begin{aligned} p= & {} \frac{\pi F(\widetilde{x})\mathbb {E}\left( x|x\le \widetilde{x}\right) +(1-\pi )F(p)\mathbb {E}\left( x|x\le p\right) }{\pi F(\widetilde{x})+(1-\pi )F(p)} \\= & {} \frac{\pi \int _{x_{L}}^{\widetilde{x}}x\mathrm{d}F(x)+(1-\pi )\int _{x_{L}}^{p}x\mathrm{d}F(x)}{\pi F(\widetilde{x})+(1-\pi )F(p)} \\\le & {} \frac{\pi \int _{x_{L}}^{\widetilde{x}}\widetilde{x}\mathrm{d}F(x)+(1-\pi )\int _{x_{L}}^{p}p\mathrm{d}F(x)}{\pi F(\widetilde{x})+(1-\pi )F(p)} \\= & {} \frac{\pi \widetilde{x}F(\widetilde{x})+(1-\pi )pF(p)}{\pi F(\widetilde{x} )+(1-\pi )F(p)}, \end{aligned}$$

where the inequality strictly holds iff \(x>x_{L}\). Thus we have

$$\begin{aligned} p\le \frac{\pi \widetilde{x}F(\widetilde{x})+(1-\pi )pF(p)}{\pi F( \widetilde{x})+(1-\pi )F(p)}. \end{aligned}$$

Multiplying both side of this inequality with \(\pi F(\widetilde{x})+(1-\pi )F(p)\) and rearranging then yields \(p\le \widetilde{x}\), where the equality holds iff \(\widetilde{x}=x_{L}(=p)\).

Secondly, Eq. (3) can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} G(p,\widetilde{x},\pi )\equiv \pi \int _{x_{L}}^{\widetilde{x}}x\mathrm{d}F(x)+(1-\pi )\int _{x_{L}}^{p}x\mathrm{d}F(x)-\pi pF(\widetilde{x})-(1-\pi )pF(p)=0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus we have

$$\begin{aligned} G_{p}\equiv \frac{\partial G}{\partial p}= & {} -[\pi F(\widetilde{x})+(1-\pi )F(p)]<0 \\ G_{\widetilde{x}}\equiv \frac{\partial G}{\partial \widetilde{x}}= & {} \pi ( \widetilde{x}-p)f(\widetilde{x})>0 \end{aligned}$$

According to Implicit Function Theorem, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dp}{d\widetilde{x}}=-\frac{G_{\widetilde{x}}}{G_{p}}=>0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus we can denote the above result as \(p=P_{AS}(\widetilde{x},\pi )\), which is an increasing function of \(\widetilde{x}\). Furthermore, since \(\widetilde{x}\ge x_{L}\), we immediately have \(p\ge x_{L}\). When \(\widetilde{x}=x_{L}\), Eq. (3) is reduced as follows.

$$\begin{aligned} p=\frac{\int _{x_{L}}^{p}x\mathrm{d}F(x)}{F(p)}=\mathbb {E}(x|x\le p), \end{aligned}$$

which is a classic problem of adverse selection by Akerlof (1970) and the unique solution is \(p=x_{L}\). As a result, \(P_{AS}(\widetilde{x} =x_{L})=x_{L}\) and thus \(p\ge x_{L}\). So far we finish the proof that \(x_{L}\le p\le \widetilde{x}\), where both inequality strictly holds if \(\widetilde{x}>x_{L}\).

Moreover, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial G}{\partial \pi }=\left[ \int _{x_{L}}^{\widetilde{x} }x\mathrm{d}F(x)-pF(\widetilde{x})\right] -\left[ \int _{x_{L}}^{p}x\mathrm{d}F(x)-pF(p)\right] \end{aligned}$$

Define \(H\left( a;p\right) \equiv \int _{x_{L}}^{a}x\mathrm{d}F(x)-pF\left( a\right)\). Then we have \(\frac{\partial H}{\partial a}=\left( a-p\right) f\left( a\right)\) and thus \(H\left( a;p\right)\) increases with a when \(a>p\). Since \(\widetilde{x}>p\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} G_{\pi }\equiv \frac{\partial G}{\partial \pi }=H\left( \widetilde{x} ;p\right) -H\left( p;p\right) >0, \end{aligned}$$

which in turn, by using Implicit Function Theorem again, implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dp}{d\pi }=-\frac{G_{\pi }}{G_{p}}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Denote \(p=P_{AS}(\widetilde{x},\pi )\). Then we know that \(p\le P_{AS}( \widetilde{x},\pi =1)=\mathbb {E}(x|x\le \widetilde{x})\le \mathbb {E} (x|x\le x_{H})\).

Finally, when \(\pi =0\), Eq. (3) is reduced to

$$\begin{aligned} p=\frac{\int _{x_{L}}^{p}x\mathrm{d}F(x)}{F(p)}=\mathbb {E}(x|x\le p), \end{aligned}$$

which has been discussed above in the case when \(\widetilde{x}=x_{L}\). The only solution is \(p=P_{AS}(\widetilde{x},\pi =0)=x_{L}\) and CM totally collapses.

Finally, when \(x\overset{U}{\sim }X\left[ x_{L},x_{H}\right] =\left[ 0,1 \right]\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} F(x)= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} 0 &{} if\,\,x<x_{L} \\ \frac{x-x_{L}}{x_{H}-x_{L}}=x &{} if\,\,x_{L}\le x\le x_{H} \\ 1 &{} if\,\,x>x_{H} \end{array}\right. } . \end{aligned}$$

Substituting F(x) into Eq. (3) and making some algebraic manipulation yields Eq. (4). \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 2:

We immediately obtain the results by combining the free entry condition in Sect. 2.5 with Cobb–Douglas matching function. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 3:

Combining Proposition 2, Lemma 1 , and Lemma 2 yields the closed-form solutions in Proposition 3. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 4, Proposition 5, Proposition 6 and Corollary 2:

With some algebraic manipulation, we can obtain the results as we did for proofs in the baseline model. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 7:

The proof is similar to that for Lemma 2, and thus omitted here. \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 3 and Proposition 8:

The first part is proved as below. To ease illustration while preserving the key insights, we have assumed that information cost \(\kappa\) is low enough such that \(b>s\) is always true in equilibrium. In turn, we have \(\frac{m(b,s) }{s}=\lambda \in (0,1)\), a constant. This would help us focus on characterizing optimal contract by buyers. We break down the proof into the following steps.

First of all, since sellers could always seller their assets at price p in CM and \(\delta \in [0,1]\), buyers in DM would have no customers if \(U(x,\delta )<p\). Meanwhile, to recover information cost, buyers in DM ex ante would never accept sellers with \(x<p\).

Secondly, for seller-\((x,\delta )\) self-selecting into DM and is allowed to trade with buyers there, denote \(\widetilde{\delta }(x)=\min \left\{ \frac{p}{x},1\right\} =\frac{p}{x}\). Since Then we can check that \(\underline{\delta }(x)\le \widetilde{\delta }(x)\le \overline{\delta }(x)\) , where \(\underline{\delta }(x)\) and \(\overline{\delta }(x)\) are characterized in the proof of Lemma 1. For each x, buyers launch direct mechanism for two groups respectively. One is \(\delta \in \varDelta _{1}=\left[ \underline{\delta }(x),\widetilde{\delta }(x)\right]\) while the other group is \(\delta \in \varDelta _{2}=[\widetilde{\delta }(x),\overline{\delta }(x)]\). On one hand, for each group, buyers make sure IR and IC conditions are satisfied. On the other hand, buyers have to make sure sellers in group \(\varDelta _{1}\cup \varDelta _{2}\) would have no incentive to deviate the other group. After all, even though x is verifiable after buyers incur information cost, \(\delta\) is still unobservable. As a result, incentive compatibility of not deviating to another group has to be additionally taken into account. In the next two pieces of analysis, we first solve the within-group contract and then go to discussion of IC on across-group.

Buyer’s objective function for group \(\varDelta _{1}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi _{B}(x)|_{\varDelta _{1}}\equiv \underset{\left\{ q(x,\delta )\in [0,1],\tau (x,\delta )\in [0,\infty )\right\} }{max}\left\{ \int _{ \underline{\delta }(x)}^{\widetilde{\delta }(x)}\left[ -\tau (x,\delta )+q(x,\delta )\cdot x\right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$

Meanwhile, for group with \(\delta \in \varDelta _{1}\), the outside option is simplified as \(V\left( x,\delta ,p\right) \equiv \delta x+\frac{1}{\lambda } \max \left\{ p-\delta x,0\right\} =\frac{p}{\lambda }-\left( \frac{1}{ \lambda }-1\right) \delta x\). That is, for sellers in this group, the outside option decreases with \(\delta\). Following Maggi and Rodriguez-Clare (1995), among others, we define \(\varUpsilon (x,\delta )=U(x,\delta )-V(x,\delta ,p).\) Envelope Theorem suggests

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \varUpsilon }{\partial \delta }=\left[ \frac{1}{\lambda } -q\left( x,\delta \right) \right] \cdot x. \end{aligned}$$

Thus

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ 1-q\left( x,\delta \right) \right] \delta x+\tau \left( x,\delta \right) -\left[ \frac{p}{\lambda }-\left( \frac{1}{\lambda }-1\right) \delta x\right] =\int _{\underline{\delta }(x)}^{\delta }\left[ \frac{1}{\lambda } -q(x,\delta ^{\prime })\right] x\mathrm{d}\delta ^{\prime }. \end{aligned}$$

Expressing the above equation for \(\tau (x,\delta )\) and substituting it into the buyer’s objective function for group \(\varDelta _{1}\) mentioned above, we can easily prove that, for group \(\varDelta _{1}\), \(q^{*}(x,\delta )|_{\varDelta _{1}}=1\). Substituting it into the above equation suggests that \(\tau ^{*}(x,\delta )|_{\varDelta _{1}}\) has nothing to with \(\delta\) and is thus denoted as \(\tau ^{*}(x)|_{\varDelta _{1}}\).

Similarly, we can show that \(q^{*}(x,\delta )|_{\varDelta _{2}}=1\) and \(\tau ^{*}(x,\delta )|_{\varDelta _{2}}\) also has nothing to do with \(\delta\) and is thus denoted as \(\tau ^{*}(x)|_{\varDelta _{2}}\). Finally, to make sure the IC condition of across-group is satisfied, we have to make sure \(\tau ^{*}(x,\delta )|_{\varDelta _{1}}=\tau ^{*}(x,\delta )|_{\varDelta _{1}}\equiv \tau (x)|_{\varDelta _{1}\cup \varDelta _{2}}=\tau (x)\). In sum, given \(x>p\) and buyers and sellers are matched in DM, the optimal contract would take the form as \(\{q^{*}(x,\delta )=1,\tau ^{*}(x,\delta )=\tau (x)\}\). It is obvious that \(\tau (x)\le x\) is always held.

In turn, we have \(U(x,\delta )=\tau (x)\) and thus

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{\delta }(x)= & {} \max \left\{ 0,\frac{p-\lambda \cdot \tau (x)}{ (1-\lambda )\cdot x}\right\} \\ \overline{\delta }(x)= & {} \min \left\{ 1,\frac{\tau (x)}{x}\right\} =\frac{ \tau (x)}{x}. \end{aligned}$$

As a recap, buyer’s profit function focusing on sellers with x is

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi _{B}(x)\equiv \underset{\left\{ q(x,\delta )\in [0,1],\tau (x,\delta )\in [0,\infty )\right\} _{\mathbf {Z}_{DM}|x}}{\max } \left\{ \int _{\delta \in \mathbf {Z}_{DM}|x}\left[ -\tau (x,\delta )+q(x,\delta )\cdot x\right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$

Using the optimal contract and cut-off values just obtained above, \(\varPi _{B}(x)\) is refined as below.

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi _{B}(x)=\underset{\tau (x,\delta )\in [0,x]}{\max }\left[ x-\tau (x)\right] \left[ G(\overline{\delta }(x))-G(\underline{\delta }(x))\right] . \end{aligned}$$

subject to

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{\delta }(x)= & {} \max \left\{ 0,\frac{p-\lambda \cdot \tau (x)}{ (1-\lambda )\cdot x}\right\} , \\ \overline{\delta }(x)= & {} \min \left\{ 1,\frac{\tau (x)}{x}\right\} =\frac{ \tau (x)}{x}, \end{aligned}$$

where G denotes the CDF of \(\delta\) with support [0, 1]. If we further assume \(\delta \overset{U}{\sim }\varDelta =[0,1]\), then we obtain \(\tau (x)\) as that in Proposition 5. In turn, we obtain \(\underline{\delta }(x)\) and \(\overline{\delta }(x)\) as in the second part of this proposition. \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 4, Proposition 9 and Corollary 3:

The right panel features the payoff in (10) of the extended model. Since the matching probability of the informed CM tends to be higher than that of the DM, the payoff slope of the former case is steeper than that of the latter case. Then we immediately obtain Lemma 4.

Now we move on to prove Proposition 9. Given its existence, the equilibrium consists of the cutoffs \(\left\{ \tilde{x}_{1}, \tilde{x}_{2}\right\}\), an equilibrium price p, and the market tightness \(\left\{ b_{1}/s_{1},b_{2}/s_{2}\right\}\) such that:

$$\begin{aligned}&p=\frac{\pi F(\widetilde{x}_{1})\mathbb {E}(x|x\le \widetilde{x_{1}})+(1-\pi )F(p)\mathbb {E}(x|x\le p)}{\pi F(\widetilde{x_{1}})+(1-\pi )F(p)},\\&q_{b}^{DM}(1-\eta )\mathbb {E}(x|\widetilde{x}_{2}\ge x\ge \widetilde{x} _{1})=\kappa ,\\&q_{b}^{CM}(1-\eta )\left[ \mathbb {E}(x|x\ge \widetilde{x}_{2})\right] =\kappa ,\\&q_{s}^{DM}\eta \widetilde{x}_{1}=p,\\&q_{s}^{CM}\eta \widetilde{x}_{2}-\kappa _{I}=q_{s}^{DM}\eta \widetilde{x} _{2}, \end{aligned}$$

where the matching probability of buyers and sellers are respectively given by \(q_{b}^{DM}=\lambda _{1}\left( \frac{b_{1}}{s_{1}}\right) ^{m-1}\), \(q_{s}^{DM}=\lambda _{1}\left( \frac{b_{1}}{s_{1}}\right) ^{m},q_{b}^{CM}=\lambda _{2}\left( \frac{b_{2}}{s_{2}}\right) ^{m-1}\) and \(q_{s}^{CM}=\lambda _{2}\left( \frac{b_{2}}{s_{2}}\right) ^{m}\). The first equation is the same as pricing equation as in the benchmark model, and can be solved as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{p}{\widetilde{x}_{1}}=\frac{\sqrt{\pi }}{1+\sqrt{\pi }}=\varphi \left( \pi \right) , \end{aligned}$$

One can plug this relation into the second equation:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{1}^{\frac{1}{m}}\left( \frac{\varphi \left( \pi \right) }{\eta } \right) ^{\frac{m-1}{m}}(1-\eta )\frac{\widetilde{x}_{1}+\widetilde{x}_{2}}{2 }=\kappa \end{aligned}$$

This delivers

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{x}_{1}=\frac{2\kappa }{\lambda _{1}^{\frac{1}{m}}\left( \frac{ \varphi \left( \pi \right) }{\eta }\right) ^{\frac{m-1}{m}}(1-\eta )}- \widetilde{x}_{2}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

This expression is analogous to the benchmark model but now the upper bound is replaced by \(\widetilde{x}_{2}\).

Then we move to characterizing \(\widetilde{x}_{2}.\) The equation is given by the buyer’s zero profit condition, with the matching probability substituted in using seller’s indifference condition:

$$\begin{aligned} \varGamma \left( \widetilde{x}_{2}\right) =\kappa \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \varGamma \left( \widetilde{x}_{2}\right) \equiv \lambda _{2}^{\frac{1}{m} }\left( \frac{\eta }{\varphi \left( \pi \right) +\frac{\kappa _{I}}{ \widetilde{x}_{2}}}\right) ^{\frac{1-m}{m}}\left( 1-\eta \right) \frac{1+ \widetilde{x}_{2}}{2}. \end{aligned}$$

This is a nonlinear equation with respect to \(\widetilde{x}_{2}\). Since the matching elasticity \(m\in \left( 0,1\right)\), we can easily verify that \(\varGamma \left( \widetilde{x}_{2}\right)\) strictly increases with \(\widetilde{x}_{2}\), and thus \(\widetilde{x}_{2}\) is unique if any solution to \(\widetilde{x}_{2}\) exists.

In the remaining part, we need to characterize the parameter region that sustains the conjecture that \(0<\widetilde{x}_{1}<\widetilde{x}_{2}<1\). To start with, substitute expression of \(\widetilde{x}_{1}\) (equation (A.1 )) into the inequality, we obtain a series of inequalities regarding \(\widetilde{x}_{2}\):

$$\begin{aligned} 0<\widetilde{x}_{1}=\frac{2\kappa }{\lambda _{1}^{\frac{1}{m}}\left( \frac{ \varphi \left( \pi \right) }{\eta }\right) ^{\frac{m-1}{m}}(1-\eta )}- \widetilde{x}_{2}<\widetilde{x}_{2}<1, \end{aligned}$$

The next lemma shows that the series of inequalities are equivalent to the following bound restrictions on \(\widetilde{x}_{2}\): \(\square\)

Lemma 5

Given the existence of \(\left( \widetilde{x}_{1},\widetilde{x}_{2}\right)\), the sufficient and necessary condition for \(0<\widetilde{x}_{1}<\widetilde{x} _{2}<1\) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} x^{*}<\widetilde{x}_{2}<x^{**}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

where

$$\begin{aligned} x^{*}\equiv & {} \frac{\kappa }{\lambda _{1}^{\frac{1}{m}}\left( \frac{ \eta }{\varphi \left( \pi \right) }\right) ^{\frac{1-m}{m}}(1-\eta )}, \\ x^{**}\equiv & {} \min \left\{ 2\frac{\kappa }{\lambda _{1}^{\frac{1}{m }}\left( \frac{\eta }{\varphi \left( \pi \right) }\right) ^{\frac{1-m}{m} }(1-\eta )},1\right\} . \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(x^{*}\) is derived under the second inequality \(\frac{2\kappa }{\lambda _{1}^{\frac{1}{m}}\left( \frac{\varphi \left( \pi \right) }{\eta } \right) ^{\frac{m-1}{m}}(1-\eta )}-\widetilde{x}_{2}<\widetilde{x}_{2}\) while \(x^{**}\) is derived under the first inequality \(0<\frac{ 2\kappa }{\lambda _{1}^{\frac{1}{m}}\left( \frac{\varphi \left( \pi \right) }{\eta }\right) ^{\frac{m-1}{m}}(1-\eta )}-\widetilde{x}_{2}\) and the last inequality \(\widetilde{x}_{2}<1.\)

Given the above, lemma, we can apply \(\varGamma \left( .\right)\) operation to the inequality (A.3). This yields \(\varGamma \left( x^{*}\right)<\varGamma \left( \widetilde{x}_{2}\right) <\varGamma \left( x^{**}\right)\), or equivalently, \(\varGamma \left( x^{*}\right)<\kappa <\varGamma \left( x^{**}\right)\). Plugging in the expressions of \(x^{*}\) and \(x^{**},\) one can show, after algebraic manipulation, that this equation is equivalent to the following restriction on \(\lambda _{2}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^{*}<\lambda _{2}<\lambda ^{**}, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^{*}\equiv & {} \left[ \frac{2\kappa }{\left( \frac{\eta }{\varphi \left( \pi \right) +\kappa _{I}/x^{**}}\right) ^{\frac{1-m}{m} }\left( 1-\eta \right) \left( 1+x^{**}\right) }\right] ^{m}, \\ \lambda ^{**}\equiv & {} \left[ \frac{2\kappa }{\left( \frac{\eta }{ \varphi \left( \pi \right) +\kappa _{I}/x^{*}}\right) ^{\frac{1-m}{m} }\left( 1-\eta \right) \left( 1+x^{*}\right) }\right] ^{m}. \end{aligned}$$

The above condition for \(\lambda\) summarizes the condition under which those three markets coexist with each other. Similarly, we can obtain the other two conditions as in Proposition 9.

Finally, we address the effect of \(\lambda _{1}\) on the total volume of trade in DM. Lemma 4 reveals the trade volume in DM is given by \(F\left( \widetilde{x}_{2}\right) -F\left( \widetilde{x}_{1}\right)\). Combining Eq. (A.1) and (A.2) immediately reaches Corollary 3.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cai, Z., Dong, F. A Model of Secular Migration from Centralized to Decentralized Trade. Econ Theory 72, 201–244 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-020-01280-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-020-01280-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation