Skip to main content
Log in

Household debt and housing bubbles: a Minskian approach to boom-bust cycles

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines macroeconomic dynamics of household debt and housing prices in a two-class economy. Drawing on Minsky’s insights into financial instability and cycles, our framework combines household debt dynamics with behavioral asset price dynamics in a Keynesian macro model. We show that endogenous boom-bust cycles can emerge through the interaction between household debt and housing price dynamics. In this model, a long period of housing bubbles is characterized by increases in the profit share and the workers’ indebtedness for most of the time. The long waves are combined with a Kaldorian model of short-run business cycles.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Minsky often argued that the household sector plays only a secondary role in the mechanism of instability because ‘Household debt-financing of consumption is almost always hedge-financing’. Minsky (1982)[p.32]

  2. The neglect of asset prices in the post-Keynesian models is somewhat curious. Many of those models are motivated by Minsky’s theory of instability, but Minsky’s emphasis on asset prices and their role in financial instability has been largely left out of the scene.

  3. The idea dates back to Keynes (1930) and Robertson (1933). Hahn (1951) applies the same mechanism to a short-run macro model.

  4. Minsky argues ‘The more severe depressions of history occur after a period of good economic performance, with only minor cycles disturbing a generally expanding economy’(Minsky 1995)[p.85] and ‘the stable mechanism which has generated the long swings centers around the cumulative changes in financial variables that take place over the long-swing expansions and contractions’. (Minsky 1964) [p.324] Palley (2011) stresses the importance of Minsky’s idea of long cycles. Ryoo (2010, 2013a, ??b, ??c) advocates the long-wave interpretation of Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis and provides formal models of Minskian long waves.

  5. How close our Harrodian formulation is to Minsky’s own writings may be an open question. The role of capacity utilization in Minsky’s theory remains ambiguous. In some places, Minsky (1964, 1995), as opposed to many Kaleckian models, takes for granted the instability in the goods market by suggesting that the multiplier-accelerator interaction (strong effect of utilization on investment) makes the goods market unstable under ‘reasonable values of the parameters’. (Minsky 1995) [p.84] This has a strong Harrodian flavor. Note that Minsky’s extensive use of Kalecki’s ‘profit equation’ [=the IS relation] does not show anything as to the precise adjustment mechanism in the goods market, and has nothing to do with what he would say about the usual Kalekckian assumption of stability in the goods market. In most of Minsky’s other writings, capacity utilization does not play a pronounced expositional role in the determination of investment, which is itself explained almost exclusively by his two-price theory. Minsky often expresses skepticism about the existence of a definite link between utilization and investment: ‘...the signals from current utilization rates to investment demand can be apt, non-existent, weak, or perverse depending upon relations and institutions that reflect the history of the economy’ (Minsky 1982)[p.96]

  6. The utilization rate is defined as the ratio of actual output to full capacity output and \(\frac {Y(t)}{Y^{f}(t)}= \frac {Y(t)}{K(t)}\cdot \frac {K(t)}{Y^{f}(t)} =\frac {u(t)}{\sigma }\). Since σ is constant, \(\frac {Y(t)}{Y^{f}(t)}\) can be proxied by u(t).

  7. The assumptions regarding accumulation behavior have been contentious in the post Keynesian/structuralist literature. Unlike our Harrodian perspective, Kaleckian models assume either that the actual utilization rate does not have to equal the desired rate even in the long-run or that the desired rate itself adjusts to the actual rate in the face of persistent discrepancies between the two rates. The mechanisms and the properties of the models depend critically on the nature of invesment behavior. Palley (2010), Dutt (2006) and Isaac and Kim (2013), for instance, study the issues of consumer debt in Kaleckian models.

  8. Our focus on long-run financial dynamics is in line with Minsky’s own interpretation of his financial instability hypothesis as a theory of long waves.

  9. The analysis can be extended to allow exogenous Harrod-neutral technical progress. The analytic results, however, will be different in a Lewis-type labor-surplus economy or in an economy where technical progress responds to the scarcity of labor supply.

  10. Let g(t) the actual growth rate of capital stock K(t), i.e., \(g(t)=\dot K(t)/K(t)\). \(\overline g(t)\) is the average value of g(t) over sufficiently long periods.

  11. Also see Fazzari et al. (2013) and Skott (2015) and Von Arnim and Barrales (2015) for a recent contribution of a model with Harrodian instability.

  12. See Ryoo (2010) for details.

  13. If retained earnings exceed investment, firms buy back their stocks from shareholders. Increasing stock buybacks have been a characteristic feature of the U.S. economy since the early 1980s (Skott and Ryoo 2008).

  14. Even with H w fixed, the distribution of the housing stock changes as a result of the transactions among worker households. The current framework allows housing rental within class, but not between classes. Any rental income on housing is netted out by the rental payment of other members within the same class. To be concrete, consider

    $$\dot C^{w}+{R^{w}_{p}}+p^{h} \dot {H^{w}_{d}}+\dot D^{w}= W+{R^{w}_{i}}+i \dot D^{w}+p^{h} \dot {H^{d}_{s}} -i \dot {M^{w}_{h}}- i \dot {M^{w}_{o}} + \dot {M^{w}_{h}} +\dot {M^{w}_{o}}. $$

    where \(\dot {H^{w}_{d}}\) and \(\dot {H^{w}_{s}}\) are the purchase and sale of houses; p h the housing price; W wage income; i the nominal interest rate; \({R^{w}_{p}}\) and \({R^{w}_{i}}\) rental payment and income, respectively; \({M^{w}_{h}}\) and \({M^{w}_{o}}\) the stock of home mortgages and other debts; D w workers’ bank deposits. The payment and the receipt of housing rents are netted out R p = R i; the assumption of constant housing stock means \({H^{w}_{d}}={H^{w}_{s}}\); setting \(M={M^{w}_{h}}+{M^{w}_{o}}-D^{w}\), we obtain the budget equation (7).

  15. The assumption of constant housing stock is also found in Iacoviello (2005)

  16. The assumption can be relaxed without affecting the main results by allowing a margin between the two rates which may depend positively on the workers’ indebtedness, assuming bankers’ profits from the existence of the margin are fully distributed to capitalists’ households.

  17. Throughout this paper, nominal (real) variables are normalized by the value of (real) capital. Due to our long-run assumption that capital grows at the natural rate on average, the quantity of a normalized variable is proportional to the quantity in per capita terms (or in efficiency units).

  18. Dutt (2006), Palley (2010), Charpe et al. (2012) and Isaac and Kim (2013) also consider credit-constrained borrowers, but they do so without introducing the effect of asset prices on credit supply.

  19. A literature has studied the implications of the collateral-credit-consumption nexus for the monetary transmission mechanism, e.g., Aoki et al. (2004) and Iacoviello (2005).

  20. Equation 8 can be rewritten as \(\hat M(t) = \hat p(t)+n + [\mu \left (y^{w}(t), \omega ^{w}(t) \right )/m(t)]\), implying bankers keep the growth of outstanding loans in line with the sum of the long-run average rates of inflation and economic growth (\(\hat p +n \)) if the workers’ profile of income and net worth satisfies \(\dot m=\mu \left (y^{w}(t), \omega ^{w}(t) \right )=0\). Higher (lower) income or net worth accelerates credit supply at a rate above (below) \(\hat p +n \).

  21. The early introduction of stock-flow specifications of consumption/portfolio behavior is found in Skott (1981).

  22. The housing market will be always in equilibrium if it instantaneously establishes the real housing price at p h(t)/p(t) = η(ρ e(t))C w(t)/H w. Our specification (13) introduces the sluggish adjustment of the real housing price. Whether this specification is plausible is an empirical question. Perhaps a more desirable specification is to model the dynamics of nominal housing prices and output prices separately. This requires the explicit modeling of price- and wage-inflation process.

  23. Setting the constant term equal to n in Eq. 13 may seem artificial, but is an innocuous assumption. Alternatively, one can set the constant term equal to an arbitrary constant κ 0:

    $$\widehat {p^{h}(t)/p(t)} = \kappa_{0} +\kappa \left (\frac{H^{d}(t)-H_{w}}{H^{w}}\right) $$

    This specification implies that there is a certain amount of excess demand or supply in the housing market in the steady state if κ 0n. The steady state gap is given by \(\frac {H^{d}(t)-H_{w}}{H^{w}}=\frac {n -\kappa _{0}}{\kappa }\). Except for this feature, all qualitative results based on Eq. 13 from the following analysis will remain valid under the alternative specification.

  24. Endogenous changes in portfolios play an important role in many models of boom-bust cycles. See, for instance, Taylor and O’Connell (1985), Asada et al. (2010), (Ryoo 2010, 2013b), and Skott (2013).

  25. If firms retain a fraction of profits, the saving propensity out of profits will be greater than that of wages, even if there is no difference in personal saving rates.

  26. We assume throughout this paper that the relevant functions are continuously differentiable.

  27. Formally, we have:

    $${c^{w}}^{\prime}(m)= \frac{-f_{y} [rs_{f}+n (1-s_{f})]-f_{\omega}(1+\alpha)}{1-f_{y} (1-s_{f})}<0. $$
  28. Since c w is decreasing in h(t), \(\eta (n) c^{w}(\tilde m^{*}(h^{+}))>0\) implies \(\eta (n) c^{w}(\tilde m^{*}(0))>0\).

  29. The expression for F m G h F h G m is found in the proof of Proposition 7 in the Appendix.

  30. Figures 1 and 2 are based on the same parameter values and functions: u = 0.5, δ = 0.08, s f=0.5, r = 0.03, α = 1, n = 0.03, μ(y w(t), ω w(t)) = 0.1y w(t)+0.1ω w(t)−0.0606, f(y l(t), ω l(t)) = 0.75y l(t)+0.048ω l(t), κ = 0.2, ν = 0.2, and η(ρ e(t)) = 1.733+ tanh[23(ρ e−0.03)]. The purpose of the simulation is to demonstrate the emergence of endogenous cycles itself, and producing realistic details of long waves, including the asymmetry of boom and bust, may require the precise calibration of functional forms as well as parameter values.

  31. Equation 43 may be seen as a special case of the general specification where accumulation is affected by the firms’ longer-run expectations of sales growth as well as the current utilization gap. This assumes that the firms’ longer-run expectations of sales growth are anchored by the natural rate of growth. The analysis of the general case is given in Section 6.1.

  32. A higher rate of employment, for instance, tends to raise recruitment costs and shop-floor militancy, which make it difficult for firms to expand production. Skott (1989) [chapter 4] discusses the behavioral foundation of Eq. 46 in greater detail.

  33. Figures 6, 7, 8 and 9 are based on the five dimensional system of Eqs. 38, 39, 40, 47, and 48 where g(t) = 0.03+1.12(u(t)−u d), \(g^{y}(t)=-0.035+\frac {0.10}{1+\exp [-64.5 \pi ^{s}(t)-14 \ln (1.1-e(t))-3.33]}\), and other parameters and functions are the same as those in footnote 30.

  34. These results are vindicated through numerical experiments. Simulation details are available upon request.

  35. The specification of housing supply (62) and its interpretation are suggested by Peter Skott.

  36. The similar assumption on the relation between housing supply and housing price is also found in Poterba (1984).

  37. Note that this feature – no effect of the construction sector on the goods market equilibrium condition – results from our special assumption on the construction sector – construction requires no labor input but only a certain amount of final goods in the form of adjustment cost – as well as our specification of workers’ consumption behavior. Thus it should not be taken as a general feature.

  38. Suppose the demand for the flow of housing services is decreasing in the rental rate and the flow supply is increasing in the stock of houses. The temporary equilibrium between supply and demand makes the equilibrium rental rate decreasing in the stock of houses.

  39. Note that the partial derivative of the left-hand side of Eq. 72 with respect to h w(t) equals \(\frac {\eta ^{\prime } R^{\prime }}{\psi ^{-1}(n)}+{\eta c^{w}}^{\prime } {\tilde m}^{\prime } -1<0\).

  40. If the housing construction is driven by the expected housing price, p he(t), rather than the actual price, i.e., \(\hat H(t) = \psi (p^{he}(t)/ p(t))\), and the process of expectations formation is adaptive, destabilizing forces of the system are likely to be stronger. The expected housing price that lags behind the actual price during a boom means the speed of the housing construction is more sluggish than in the case where the construction is determined by the actual price. Next, the construction may require borrowing and this aspect also affects the implication of construction activities for housing market dynamics, but our simple specification of housing construction does not allow us to pursue such an issue.

  41. The simple process of adaptive expectations can emerge from the process of econometric learning under constant-gain algorithms (Evans and Honkapohja 2001).

  42. For instance, see Blanchard (2008) for a discussion of the state of macroeconomics.

References

  • Aoki K, Proudman J, Vlieghe G (2004) House prices, consumption, and monetary policy: a financial accelerator approach. J Financ Intermed 13(4)

  • Asada T, Chiarella C, Flaschel P, Mouakil T, Proaño CR, Semmler W (2010) Stabilizing an unstable economy: On the choice of proper policy measures. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 4 (2010-21). 10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2010-21

  • Beja A, Goldman MB (1980) On the dynamic behavior of prices in disequilibrium. J Financ 35(2):235–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O (2008) The state of macro NBER Working Papers 14259, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc

  • Brock WA, Hommes CH (1998) Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. J Econ Dyn Control 22(8-9):1235–1274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charpe M, Flaschel P, Proaño CR (2012) Income distribution, credit rationing and households’ debt. Metroeconomica 63(3):458–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charpe M, Flaschel P, Proaño CR, Semmler W (2009) Over-consumption, credit rationing and bailout monetary policy: A Minskyan perspective intervention. Eur J Econ Econ Policies 6(2):247–270

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiarella C (1992) The dynamics of speculative behaviour. Ann Oper Res 37:101–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiarella C, Di Guilmi C (2011) The financial instability hypothesis: A stochastic microfoundation framework. J Econ Dyn Control 35(8):1151–1171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutt AK (2006) Maturity, stagnation and consumer debt: a stendlian approach. Metroeconomica 57(3):339–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans G, Honkapohja S (2001) Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics. Frontiers of Economic Research. Princeton University Press

  • Fazzari S, Ferri P, Greenberg E (2008) Cash flow, investment, and Keynes-Minsky cycles. J Econ Behav Organ 65(3-4):555–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fazzari SM, Ferri PE, Greenberg EG, Variato AM (2013) Aggregate demand, instability, and growth. Rev Keynesian Econ 1(1):1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foley DK (1987) Liquidity-profit rate cycles in a capitalist economy. J Econ Behav Organ 8(3):363–376

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahn FH (1951) The share of wages in the national income. Oxf Econ Pap 3(2):147–157

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrod R (1939) An essay in dynamic theory. Econ J 49:14–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch MW, Smale S (1974) Differential Equations, Dynamical systems, and Linear Algebra. Academic Press, San Diego, New York, Boston, London Sydney, Tokyo, Toronto

  • Iacoviello M (2005) House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. Am Econ Rev 95(3):739–764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isaac AG, Kim YK (2013) Consumer and corporate debt: A neo-Kaleckian synthesis. Metroeconomica 64(2):244–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor N (1956) Alternative theories of distribution. Rev Econ Stud 23(2):83–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor N (1966) Marginal productivity and the macro-economic theories of distribution: Comment on Samuelson and Modigliani. Rev Econ Stud 33(4):309–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1930) A treatise on money. Macmillan, London and Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky H (1982) Can It happen again?: essays on instability and finance. M.E. Sharpe

  • Minsky H (1986) Stabilizing an Unstable Economy: A Twentieth Century Fund Report. A Twentieth Century Fund report. Yale University Press

  • Minsky HP (1964) Longer waves in financial relations: financial factors in the more severe depressions. Am Econ Rev 54(3):324–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky HP (1995) Longer waves in financial relations: financial factors in the more severe depressions II. J Econ Issues 29(1):83–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minsky HP (1996) The essential characteristics of Post Keynesian economics. In: Deleplace G., Nell E. (eds) Money in Motion: The Post Keynesian and Circulation Approaches. St. Martin’s Press, Inc., New York, New York, Ch. 2, pp 70–88

  • Palley TI (1994) Debt, aggregate demand, and the business cycle: An analysis in the spirit of Kaldor and Minsky. J Post Keynesian Econ 16(3):371–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palley TI (1996) Inside debt, aggregate demand, and the Cambridge theory of distribution. Camb J Econ 20(4):465–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palley TI (2010) Inside debt and economic growth: A neo-Kaleckian analysis. In: Setterfield M (ed) Handbook of alternative theories of economic growth. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 293–308

  • Palley TI (2011) A theory of Minsky super-cycles and financial crises. Constit Polit Econ 30(1):31– 46

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba JM (1984) Tax subsidies to owner-occupied housing: an asset-market approach. Q J Econ 99(4):729–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robertson DH (1933) Saving and hoarding. Econ J 43(171):399–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryoo S (2010) Long waves and short cycles in a model of endogenous financial fragility. J Econ Behav Organ 74(3):163–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryoo S (2013a) Bank profitability, leverage and financial instability: a Minsky-Harrod model. Camb J Econ 37(5):1127–1160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryoo S (2013b) Minsky cycles in Keynesian models of growth and distribution. Rev Keynesian Econ 1(1):37–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryoo S (2013c) The paradox of debt and Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis. Metroeconomica 64(1):1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sethi R (1996) Endogenous regime switching in speculative markets. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 7(1):99–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skott P (1981) On the ‘Kaldorian’ Saving Function. Kyklos 34(4):563–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skott P (1989) Conflict and effective demand in economic growth. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Skott P (1994) On the modelling of systemic financial fragility. In: Dutt A (ed) New directions in analytic political economy. Edward elgar, pp 49–76

  • Skott P (2013) Increasing inequality and financial instability. Rev Radical Polit Econ 45(4):478–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skott P (2015) Growth cycles with or without price flexibility. Rev Keynesian Econ 3(3):374–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skott P, Ryoo S (2008) Macroeconomic implications of financialisation. Camb J Econ 32(6):827–862

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor L, O’Connell SA (1985) A Minsky crisis. Q J Econ 100:871–885

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Arnim R, Barrales J (2015) Demand-driven Goodwin cycles with Kaldorian and Kaleckian features. Rev Keynesian Econ 3(3):351–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am very grateful to two anonymous referees whose comments and suggestions greatly influence this version of paper. I would also like to thank Peter Skott and Gilberto Tadeu Lima for their helpful comments and suggestions on early drafts of this paper. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Soon Ryoo.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proof of Propositions 3 and 7

Proof

of Proposition 3 Let c w(m(t)) = c w. Equation 17 and Assumption (37) implies

$$ \kappa\underline \eta c^{w} < \dot h (s)+\kappa h(s)<\kappa\overline \eta c^{w} $$

Multiplying this by exp(κ s) and integrating it over [0,t] gives us

$$ [\exp(\kappa t)-1]\underline \eta c^{w}< \exp(\kappa t)h^{w}(t)-h(0)<[\exp(\kappa t)-1]\overline \eta c^{w} $$

Mutiplying by exp(−κ t) and rearranging the terms, we have:

$$ [1-\exp(-\kappa t)]\underline \eta c^{w}+\exp(-\kappa t)h(0) < h^{w}(t)<[1-\exp(-\kappa t)]\overline \eta c^{w}+\exp(-\kappa t)h(0) $$

Since 0< exp(−κ t)≤1 over t∈[0,), we have:

$$ \underline h \leq h^{w}(t) \leq \overline h $$

where \(\underline h =\min \{ \underline \eta c^{w}, h(0)\}\) and \(\overline h =\max \{ \overline \eta c^{w}, h(0)\}\). There h w(t) is bounded. Since \(\dot h^{w}(t)\) is continuous in h w(t) and η is bounded by assumption, \(\dot h^{w}(t)\) is bounded as well. To prove the boundedness of ρ e(t), consider

$$ \rho(t) =\dot h^{w}(t)/h^{w}(t)+n $$

Since \(\dot h^{w}(t)\) and h w(t) are bounded, ρ(t) is clearly bounded as long as h(0)>0. Note that, if h w(t) = 0, ρ(t) may explode but if h(0)>0, this case is ruled out: \(\underline \eta >0\) by assumption and therefore \(h^{w}(t)>\underline h \equiv \min \{\underline \eta c^{w}, h(0)\}>\)0 if h(0)>0. Because ρ(t) is bounded, the same method as in the proof of the boundedness of h w(t) can be applied to prove that of ρ e(t) by using (15). Since the trajectories are bounded and (η(n)c w, n) is a unique unstable fixed point, if \(-\kappa +\nu \left (\frac {\kappa \eta ^{\prime }}{\eta } -1\right ) >0\), the trajectories of h w(t) and ρ e(t) must converge to a closed orbit according to the Poincare-Bendixson theorem. □

Proof

of Proposition 7 To prove the boundedness of the trajectories of the 3D system, we first construct a set on the (m(t), h w(t)) space from which any trajectory cannot escape once it enters independently of the value of ρ e(t) (i.e., the projection onto the (m(t), h w(t)) space of a positively invariant set). We can confine our initial analysis to the (m(t), h w(t)) space thanks to the boundedness of η(ρ e), i.e., Assumption (37). Consider the following set:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \mathbf{A}&\equiv&\{(m(t), h(t)) \in [m_{1}-a , m_{2}+a] \times [h_{1}-a, h_{2}+a]~\vert~ \\ && a>0, ~\underline \eta \tilde c^{w} ( m_{1} , h_{1})= h_{1}, \overline \eta c^{w}( m_{2} , h_{2})= h_{2}, m_{i} = \tilde m (h_{i}), i=1,2 \} \end{array} $$

where a sufficiently small positive a can be chosen for A to include {[m 1,m 2]×[h 1,h 2]} as its proper subset and to ensure m 1a > 0 and h 1a > 0. It can be easily shown that the gradient at any point on the boundaries of A points inward the set. It can be also shown that any trajectory from an arbitrary initial condition eventually enter A. The intuitive explanation is as follows: for any given ρ e(t), the 2D sub-system (m(t), h(t)) has a unique fixed point and the fixed point is locally stable since the trace and the determinant of the subsystem are negative and positive, respectively. The fixed point depends continuously and monotonically on the value of η(ρ e(t)). The set of all fixed points of the 2D subsystem is a finite and closed segment on the \(\dot m(t)\)-nullcline (Note that the \(\dot h^{w}(t)\)-nullcline depends continuously and monotonically on the value of ρ e(t), but the area it spans is limited by the boundedness of the η-function). We can choose a set that includes the set of fixed points as a proper subset. Such a set has the desired property: any trajectory cannot escape from it. A is an example of those sets with such a property. In our proof, we used the fact that the determinant of the 2D sub-system is positive, which can be checked:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} F_{m} G_{h}-F_{h} G_{m}&=& \frac{\kappa}{1+\mu_{y} -f_{y} (1-s_{f})} \times [\{rf_{y}s_{f}+f_{\omega} (1+\alpha)\}( \mu_{y} +\eta \mu_{\omega}) \\ &&~~~~~~~~~~~+\mu_{\omega} \{1-(1-s_{f}) f_{y} \}+n \{\mu_{y} +\eta \mu_{\omega} f_{y} (1-s_{f})\}]>0 \end{array} $$

Since m(t) and h w(t) are bounded, the boundedness of ρ e(t) follows from the argument similar to that in Proposition 3. □

Appendix B: Proof of Proposition 5 and 6

Let us consider the following Jacobian Matrix evaluated at the stationary point.

$$ J=\left[\begin{array}{lll} F_{m}& F_{h^{w}} & 0 \\ G_{m}&G_{h} &G_{\rho^{e}} \\ \nu \frac{G_{m}}{h^{w*}}& \nu \frac{G_{h}}{h^{w*}} & \nu \left( \frac{G_{\rho^{e}}}{h^{w*}}-1\right) \\ \end{array}\right] $$
(73)

We have seen F m < 0 and \(\phantom {\dot {i}\!}F_{h^{w}}>0\) in Eqs. 31 and 32. We also have: \(G_{h}= \kappa (\eta \tilde {c^{w}_{h}} -1)<0\) and \(G_{\rho ^{e}}=\kappa \eta ^{\prime }\tilde c^{w}(\cdot )>0\).

Let us define \(b_{1}\equiv \frac {G_{\rho ^{e}}}{h^{w*}}-1\), \(\phantom {\dot {i}\!}b_{2}\equiv F_{m} G_{h}-F_{h^{w}} G_{m}>0\), b 3F m + G h < 0, and \(b_{4}\equiv \left (\frac {G_{\rho ^{e}}}{h^{w*}}-1\right )F_{m}- G_{h}\). Using the definition of b i ’s, we have

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\text{tr}(J)=b_{3}+b_{1}\nu, ~~~~~{\Sigma}_{i=1}^{3} J_{i}=b_{2}+ b_{4}\nu, ~~~~~\det(J)=-b_{2}\nu <0\\ &-&\text{tr}(J)({\Sigma}_{i=1}^{3} J_{i})+\det(J)=A_{0} +A_{1} \nu+A_{2}\nu^{2} \end{array} $$

where A 0=−b 2 b 3 > 0, A 1=−b 1 b 2b 3 b 4b 2, A 2=−b 1 b 4, and J i ’s are the first principal minors of J.

Proof

of Proposition 5 The Routh-Hurwitz necessary and sufficient condition for the asymptotic local stability is:

$$\text{tr}(J)<0,~~{\Sigma}_{i=1}^{3} J_{i} >0, ~~ \det(J)<0,~\text{and}~ -\text{tr}(J)({\Sigma}_{i=1}^{3} J_{i})+\det(J)>0 $$

As ν→0, we have:

$$\text{tr}(J) \rightarrow b_{3}<0, ~ {\Sigma}_{i=1}^{3} J_{i} \rightarrow b_{2}>0, ~\text{and}~ -\text{tr}(J)({\Sigma}_{i=1}^{3} J_{i})+\det(J) \rightarrow A_{0}>0 $$

It is readily seen that for a sufficiently small positive value of ν, the signs of tr(J), \({\Sigma }_{i=1}^{3} J_{i}\) and \(-\text {tr}(J)({\Sigma }_{i=1}^{3} J_{i})+\det (J)\) should be retained while det(J) being negative. □

Proof

of Proposition 6 To prove the existence of a limit cycle for the system of Eqs. 3840 , we will show that the Jacobian matrix (73) evaluated at ( m (ν), h (ν), ρ e(ν), ν), where ( m (ν), h (ν), ρ e(ν)) is a fixed point of the system, has a negative real root and a pair of imaginary roots. If we denote the eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix as λ(ν) and β(ν𝜃(ν)i, we need to show that λ(ν b) < 0, β(ν b) = 0, and 𝜃(ν b) ≠ 0. ν b is called a Hopf bifurcation point. The Routh-Hurwitz criterion states that the Jacobian matrix will have a negative real root and a pair of pure imaginary roots if and only if:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{tr}(J)<0,~&~&{\Sigma}_{i=1}^{3} J_{i} >0\\ \det(J)<0,&~& -\text{tr}(J)({\Sigma}_{i=1}^{3} J_{i})+\det(J)=0 \end{array} $$
(74)

Let us suppose that b 1 > 0 and consider two cases: b 4 > 0 and b 4 < 0

  1. Case 1.

    b 4 > 0. We then have A 2 < 0. Since A 0 > 0, the quadratic equation, A 0 + A 1 ν + A 2 ν 2=0, has one positive and one negative roots. Choose the positive root and denote it as ν . ν is given by

    $$\nu^{*} \equiv (A_{1}+\sqrt{{A_{1}^{2}}+4A_{0}\vert A_{2}\vert})/(2\vert A_{2}\vert)>0 $$

    where −tr(J)(J 1 + J 2 + J 3)+ det(J) = 0. Because b 2 > 0 and b 4 > 0, J 1 + J 2 + J 3 = b 2 + b 4 ν >0. tr(J) = 0 if \(\nu =\frac {b_{3}}{b_{1}}>0\). It implies that if \(\nu =\frac {b_{3}}{b_{1}}\), then −tr(J)(J 1 + J 2 + J 3)+ det(J) = det(J) < 0. For any ν > 0, −tr(J)(J 1 + J 2 + J 3)+ det(J) = det(J) < 0 only if ν > ν . Therefore, \(\nu ^{*}<\frac {b_{3}}{b_{1}}\). Since tr(J) is increasing in ν ( b 1 > 0), \(\nu ^{*}<\frac {b_{3}}{b_{1}}\) implies that tr(J) < 0 at ν = ν . Therefore, we conclude that if ν = ν , the Routh-Hurwitz criterion (74) is satisfied and, therefore, λ(ν ) < 0, β(ν ∗∗) = 0, and 𝜃(ν ) ≠ 0. For a later purpose, note that the first derivative of −tr(J)(J 1 + J 2 + J 3)+ det(J) with respect to ν is negative at ν = ν , i.e. A 1 + 2A 2 ν < 0.

  2. Case 2.

    Next suppose that b 4 < 0. We then have A 2 > 0, A 1 < 0 and A 0 > 0. Furthermore, a straightforward calculation shows that:

    $${A_{1}^{2}}-4A_{0}A_{2} =(b_{1}b_{2}-b_{3} b_{4})^{2}+2(b_{1}b_{2}+b_{3} b_{4})b_{2}+{b_{2}^{2}}>0 $$

    The last inequality follows from the fact that b 1 > 0, b 2 > 0, b 3 < 0 and b 4 < 0. Therefore, the quadratic equation, A 0 + A 1 ν + A 2 ν 2=0, has two distinct positive roots. Denote the smaller as ν ∗∗.

    $$\nu^{**} \equiv (\vert A_{1}\vert-\sqrt{{A_{1}^{2}}-4A_{0} A_{2}})/(2 A_{2})>0 $$

    It is simple to show that tr(J) < 0 and J 1 + J 2 + J 3 > 0 at ν = ν ∗∗. Therefore, we conclude that if ν = ν ∗∗, Eq. 74 is satisfied.

It remains to show that β (ν ) ≠ 0 and β (ν ∗∗) ≠ 0. Tedious algebra shows:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}}\beta^{\prime}(\nu^{*})&=&\frac{2\theta(\nu^{*})[b_{1}b_{2}+b_{3}b_{4}+b_{2}+2b_{1} b_{4} \nu^{*}]}{4\lambda(\nu^{*})^{2}\theta(\nu^{*})+4\theta(\nu^{*})^{3}}=\frac{-2\theta(\nu^{*})[A_{1}+2A_{2}\nu^{*}]}{4\lambda(\nu^{*})^{2}\theta(\nu^{*})+4\theta(\nu^{*})^{3}}>0\\ \beta^{\prime}(\nu^{**})&=&\frac{2\theta(\nu^{**})\left[b_{4}\lambda(\nu^{**})+ b_{1}\theta(\nu^{**})^{2}+b_{2}\right]}{4\lambda(\nu^{**})^{2}\theta(\nu^{**})+4\theta(\nu^{**})^{3}}>0 \end{array} $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ryoo, S. Household debt and housing bubbles: a Minskian approach to boom-bust cycles. J Evol Econ 26, 971–1006 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-016-0473-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-016-0473-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation