Skip to main content
Log in

Schumpeterian growth theory, Schumpeter, and growth policy design

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The purpose of this paper is to show that both Schumpeterian growth theory and Schumpeter’s own thinking can be helpful in order to think about growth policy design and the role of the state. This reflection offers an economic policy roadmap and gives rise to concrete proposals in terms of an adequate mix of demand and supply-side options depending on the country’s distance to the world technology frontier.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, they use Mincerian equations to evaluate the returns from education, and whenever these returns appear to be small, they conclude that education is not a binding constraint on growth. Or if interest rates turn out to be low, they conclude that credit is not a binding constraint on growth.

  2. The theory was initiated in the fall of 1987 at MIT. During that year Aghion and Howitt wrote their ‘model of growth through creative destruction’ which came out in print as Aghion and Howitt (1992).

  3. There is no occurrence of the term creative destruction in The Theory of Economic Development (TED; Schumpeter 1934) nor in Business Cycles (BC; Schumpeter 1939). In the TED, Schumpeter rather refers to a ‘process of liquidation’ or ‘of absorption’ between two booms (Schumpeter 1934: 244). In BC, Schumpeter refers to the notion of ‘creative response’, a notion he dedicated a paper to in 1947. This notion is very similar to the one of creative destruction. In particular, Schumpeter emphasized 3 main characteristics of a creative response: 1. It can only be understood ex post; 2. It shapes the whole course of subsequent events and their ‘long run’ outcome so that it cannot be conceived as a mere ‘transition’; 3. Its frequency and its intensity have something to do with entrepreneurial activity captured from a multidimensional perspective: quantitative, qualitative, institutional and behavioural (Schumpeter 1947: 150).

  4. See Aghion et al. (2013).

  5. This idea is not at odds with Schumpeter’s original stance at economic policy matters. Although he was in principle reluctant to derive policy implications from models far too simple to reflect important features of the real economy, there are textual evidences in favour of a judicious regulatory policy (Ordnungspolitik as opposed to Prozesspolitik) that would provide the general (and somewhat abstract) rules of the game, a policy framework that displays common features with Hurwicz’s concept of mechanism design (see Kurz in this volume).

  6. Which of these effects dominates will depend in particular upon the size of innovations: the larger the size of innovation, the smaller the productivity adjusted-wage rate, and therefore the smaller the business-stealing effect Assessing the relative importance of these two effects in practice, requires estimating the structural parameters of the growth model using micro data. Note that excessive growth is also compatible with growth models a-la-Romer (1990). See Benassy (1998).

  7. By ‘extractive economic institutions’, Acemoglu and Robinson (2002) mean practices and policies designed to extract incomes and wealth from one subset of society (the masses) to benefit a different subset (the governing elite). They are opposed to ‘inclusive economic institutions’, which must feature secure private property, an unbiased system of law, and a provision of public services that provides an environment in which people can exchange and contract; they also must permit the entry of new businesses and allow people to choose their careers.

  8. Note that, in this lecture, Schumpeter defines institutions as ‘all the patterns of behavior into which individuals must fit under penalty of encountering organized resistance, and not only legal institutions (such as property or the contract) and the agencies for their production or enforcement’(Schumpeter 1983 in Swedberg 1991: 438).

  9. This text constitutes the basis of a series of lectures that Schumpeter was scheduled to give during January 9–20, 1950, at the Charles R. Walgreen Foundation in Chicago. The day before the first lecture, however, Schumpeter died.

  10. For more details, see Festré (2002).

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2002) Why nations fail: the origins of power, prosperity and poverty. London Profile Books, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Aghion P, Zilibotti F (2006) Distance to frontier, selection, and economic growth. J Eur Econ Assoc 4(1):37–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Durlauf S (2005) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier, North-Holland

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt, P (1998) Endogenous growth theory. MIT Press

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (2009) The economics of growth. MIT Press

  • Aghion P, Roulet A (2011) Repenser l’Etat. Editions du Seuil, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Boustan L, Hoxby C, Vandenbussche J (2009) The causal impact of education on economic growth: evidence from US. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring

  • Aghion P, Dewatripont M, Hoxby C, Mas-Colell A, Sapir A (2010) The Governance and performance of Universities: evidence from Europe and the US. Econ Policy 25:7–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Dewatripont M, Du L, Harrison A, Legros P (2012a) Industrial Policy and Competition. Mimeo Harvard

  • Aghion P, Farhi, E, Kharroubi E (2012b) Monetary policy, liquidity and growth. NBER Working Paper n° 18072

  • Aghion P, Akcigit U, Howitt P (2013) What do we learn from Schumpeterian growth theory. Penn Institute for Economic Research Working Paper 13-026. http://economics.sas.upenn.edu/sites/economics.sas.upenn.edu/files/13-026.pdf

  • Aghion P, Hemous D, Kharroubi E (2014a) Cyclical fiscal policy, credit constraints, and productivity growth. J Monet Econ 62:41–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Cette G, Cohen E (2014b) Changer de modèle. Odile Jacob, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Albert M (1991) Capitalisme contre capitalisme, Editions du Seuil, Paris. Translated into English under the title Capitalism vs. capitalism

  • Andersen ES (2012) Joseph A. Schumpeter: a theory of social and economic evolution. Palgrave Macmillan

  • Arena R, Dangel-Hagnauer C (eds) (2002) The contribution of Joseph Schumpeter to economics: economic development and institutional change. Routledge, London

  • Benassy J-P (1998) Is there always too little research in endogenous growth with expanding product variety? Eur Econ Rev 42:61–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David P, Hall B (2000) Heart of darkness: modeling public-private funding inter-actions inside the R&D black box. Res Policy 29:497–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis S, Haltiwanger J (1992) Gross job creation, gross job destruction, and employment reallocation. Q J Econ 107:819–864

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov S, La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2002) The regulation of entry. Q J Econ 117:1–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs A (1957) An economic theory of democracy. Harper, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W (2005) National policies and economic growth. In: Durlauf S, Aghion P (eds) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier, North-Holland

    Google Scholar 

  • Festré A (2002) Money, banking and dynamics: two Wicksellian routes from Mises to Hayek and Schumpeter. Am J Econ Sociol 61(2): 439–480. Reprinted in: Wood, John C, Wood, Robert D. (eds), Friedrich A. Hayek: Critical Assessments of Leading Economists (vol. 4). Routledge, London, 2004, pp. 427–36

  • Festré A, Garrouste P (2008) Rationality, behavior, institutional and economic change in Schumpeter. J Econ Methodol 15:1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Festré A, Nasica E (2009) Schumpeter on money, banking and finance: an institutionalist perspective. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 16:325–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel J, Romer D (1999) Does trade cause growth? Am Econ Rev 89:379–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman C (1982) The economics of industrial innovation. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerschenkron A (1962) Economic backwardness in historical perspective. Harvard University Press

  • Guellec D, van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie B (2003) The impact of public R&D expenditures on business R&D. Econ Innov New Technol 12:225–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall B, Van Reenen J (2000) How effective are fiscal incentives for R&D? A review of the evidence. Res Policy 29:449–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann R, Rodrik D, Velasco A (2005a) Growth diagnostics. Harvard University, Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, R, Rodrik, D, Velasco A (2005b) Growth diagnostics. Manuscript, Inter-American Development Bank

  • King R, Rebelo S (1990) Public policy and economic growth: developing neoclassical implications. J Polit Econ 98:126–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lentile D, Mairesse J (2009) A policy to boost R&D: does the R&D tax credit work? EIB Papers 14:143–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Mian A, Sufi A (2012) What explains high unemployment? The aggregate demand channel. NBER Working Paper n° 17890

  • Montmartin B, Herrera B (2015) Internal and external effects of R&D subsidies and fiscal incentives: empirical evidence using spatial dynamic panel models. Res Policy 44:1065–1079

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrick D (2005) Growth strategies. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (2005)

  • Romer P (1990) Endogenous technical change. J Polit Econ 98:71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1934) The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycles. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1939) Business cycles. A theoretical, historical, and statistical analysis of the capitalist process, vol 2. Mac Graw Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1947) The creative response in economic history. J Econ Hist 7:149–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1954) History of economic analysis. Allen and Unwin, London

  • Schumpeter J (1983) American institutions and economic progress. Zitschift für die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft (J Instit Theor Econ) 139:191–196

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow R (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70:65–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence M (2009) The growth report: strategies for sustained growth and inclusive development. World Bank

  • Swedberg R (ed) (1991) Joseph A. Schumpeter: the economics and sociology of capitalism. Princeton University Press, Princeton

  • Vandenbussche J, Aghion P, Meghir C (2009) Growth, distance to frontier, and composition of human capital. J Econ Growth 11:97–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber M (1927) General economic theory. (trans: Knight FH). Greenberg Publisher Inc., New York

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Agnès Festré.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aghion, P., Festré, A. Schumpeterian growth theory, Schumpeter, and growth policy design. J Evol Econ 27, 25–42 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-016-0465-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-016-0465-5

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation