Skip to main content
Log in

Consumer well-being in a future of accelerating novelty

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Novel goods and ideas are introduced to today’s consumers with increasing frequency. This phenomenon is perhaps most notable in the apparel industry, which in recent decades has seen the rise of “fast fashion” and an accelerating rate of novel style introductions from semi-annual to semi-weekly. In this paper I study the potential for this type of accelerating novelty to have a negative impact on consumer well-being. I analyze a simple theoretical model of consumer behavior in which consumers with a preference for novelty decide how fast to replace their fashion goods before and after an innovation which accelerates the rate at which new goods become available. In the basic model, where consumers update their goods based on their intrinsic preference for novelty, the novelty-accelerating innovation is not welfare-decreasing. However, when the model is extended in realistic ways, I find that there are at least three conditions under which the innovation may decrease welfare by increasing the extent of sub-optimal replacement: if there are external costs of updating to a newer good; if the consumers are boundedly rational and exhibit present bias; or if consumers’ replacement decisions reflect an arms race for social status. My results in these model extensions provide an economic foundation for rising popular concern about undesirable social effects of “fast fashion.” I also discuss the implications of these results for future patterns of consumption, which are likely to reflect still more accelerated novelty and possibly the expansion of fashion behavior to a broader range of consumption settings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This working definition of “fashion” is similar to many others. For Pesendorfer (1995), fashion is “the opaque process that identifies certain designs, products, or social behaviors as ‘in’ for a limited period and which replaces them with infallible regularity by new designs, new products, and new forms of social behavior.” For Chai et al. (2007), it is “the tendency or behavioral norm of actors to adopt certain types or styles of customs or commodities nearly simultaneously, only to adopt a different type or style of custom or commodity in future periods.” Sproles (1981)) defines fashion in terms of social norm: “a way of behaving that is temporarily adopted by a discernible proportion of members of a social group because that chosen behavior is perceived to be socially appropriate for the time and situation.” Although the assumption that fashion changes do not involve functional changes is a common one, it is not universal. For example, Stigler and Becker (1977) claim that new styles which gain popularity are often superior to old styles. However, this implies that new fashions can actually have functional advantages, which is not the case considered here, and arguably not a reasonable assumption for many observed style changes in apparel. For example, neither bell-bottomed jeans, taper-cut jeans, nor baggy jeans offer intrinsic superiority.

  2. The legal analysis of Hemphill and Suk (2009) strongly favors this approach, as it pre-supposes the value of innovation. Following standard practice, they assume that “if consumers are prepared to pay for fashion in its various forms, regulation ought to be set to promote innovation and allow consumers a variety of options… Our view that innovation in fashion is socially desirable rests on assumptions that are shared with the assumption that in general the creation of new novels and new songs is socially desirable” (p.116).

  3. I assume that no consumer learning is necessary for new styles to be consumed, and consumers can costlessly switch to using a new style. This assumption is justified by style changes being functionally neutral. Issues of consumption routines and time constraints, as studied in Metcalfe (2001), are not modeled.

  4. I am grateful to an anonymous reviewer for raising this possibility.

References

  • Andreozzi L, Bianchi M (2007) Fashion: why people like it and theorists do not. In: Bianchi M (ed) The evolution of consumption: theories and practices. Emerald Group Publishing, Bingley

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell LS, Bernheim BD (1996) Veblen effects in a theory of conspicuous consumption. Am Econ Rev 86(3):349–373

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhardwaj V, Fairhurst A (2010) Fast fashion: response to changes in the fashion industry. Int Rev Retail Distrib Consum Res 20(1):165–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi M (2002) Novelty, preferences, and fashion: when goods are unsettling. J Econ Behav Organ 47(1):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumer H (1969) Fashion: from class differentiation to collective selection. Sociol Q 10(3):275–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caulkins JP, Hartl RF, Kort PM, Feichtinger G (2007) Explaining fashion cycles: imitators chasing innovators in product space. J Econ Dyn Control 31(5):1535–1556

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chai A, Earl P, Potts J (2007) Fashion, growth and welfare: an evolutionary approach. In: Bianchi M (ed) The evolution of consumption: theories and practices. Emerald Group Publishing, Bingley

    Google Scholar 

  • Claudio L (2007) Waste couture: environmental impact of the clothing industry. Environ Health Perspect 115(9):A449–A454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cline EL (2012) Overdressed: the shockingly high cost of cheap fashion: portfolio hardcover

  • Coelho PRP, McClure JE (2007) Toward an economic theory of fashion. Econ Inq 31(4):595--608

  • Cooper KB (2013) Trading quality and newness: income signaling and the consumption of durable visible goods. Working paper, Cornell University

  • Corneo G, Jeanne O (1997) Conspicuous consumption, snobbism and conformism. J Public Econ 66(1):55–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferdows K, Lewis MA, Machuca JAD (2004) Rapid-fire fulfillment. Harv Bus Rev 82(11):104–110

    Google Scholar 

  • Foley CA (1893) Fashion. Econ J 3(11):458–474

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank R (1985) The demand for unobservable and other nonpositional goods. Am Econ Rev 75(1):101–116

    Google Scholar 

  • Frederick S, Loewenstein G, O’Donoghue T (2002) Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. J Econ Lit 40(2):351–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hemphill CS, Suk J (2009) The law, culture, and economics of fashion. Stanford Law Rev 61(5):1147–1199

    Google Scholar 

  • Howarth RB (1996) Status effects and environmental externalities. Ecol Econ 16(1):25–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ireland NJ (1994) On limiting the market for status signals. J Public Econ 53(1):91–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson D (1997) Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Q J Econ 112(2):443–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laya P (2014) Carlos Slim mimics zara to spruce up Sears in Mexico. Bloomberg, Thursday, Sept. 25th, online edition

  • McAfee, A, Sjoman A, Dessain V (2004) Zara: IT for fast fashion. Harvard Business School Case Study 604–081

  • Metcalfe JS (2001) Consumption, preferences, and the evolutionary agenda. J Evol Econ 11(1):37–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller CM, McIntyre SH, Mantrala MK (1993) Toward formalizing fashion theory. J Mark Res 30(2):142–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris S (2012) Fast fashion and internet drive Inditex past forecasts. Reuters Wednesday, Sept. 19th, online edition

  • Nelson R, Consoli D (2010) An evolutionary theory of household consumption behavior. J Evol Econ 20(5):665–687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • New York City Economic Development Corporation (2012) Fashion.NYC.2020. Online. Available: http://www.nycedc.com/system/files/files/resource/Fashion_study.pdf

  • Pesendorfer W (1995) Design innovation and fashion cycles. Am Econ Rev 85(4):771–792

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson J (1996) Vertical integration and rapid response in fashion apparel. Organ Sci 7(4):400–412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson DE (1961) The economics of fashion demand. Q J Econ 75(3):376–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schubert C (2012) Is novelty always a good thing? Towards an evolutionary welfare economics. J Evol Econ 22(3):585–619

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwarz B (2004) The paradox of choice: why more is less. Ecco, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegle L (2011) Why fast fashion is slow death for the planet. The Observer, Saturday, May 7th, online edition

  • Simmel G (1904) Fashion. Int Q 10:130–155

    Google Scholar 

  • Sproles GB (1981) Analyzing fashion life cycles: principles and perspectives. J Mark 45(4):116–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GT, Becker GS (1977) De gustibus non est disputandum. Am Econ Rev 67(2):76–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen T (1899) The theory of the leisure class, Unwin books. reprinted Dover Publications, 1994

  • Wendner R (2003) Status, environmental externality, and optimal tax programs. Econ Bull 8(5):1–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitehead S (2014) 5 truths the fast fashion industry doesn't want you to know. Huffington Post, Tuesday, Aug. 19th, online edition

  • Witt U (2001) Learning to consume – a theory of wants and the growth of demand. J Evol Econ 11(1):23–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zarroli J (2013) In trendy world of fast fashion, styles aren’t made to last. NPR, Monday, Mar. 11th, online edition

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kristen B. Cooper.

Additional information

This paper was previously circulated with the title, “Innovation and welfare in markets for fashion goods.” I am grateful to participants at the 15th Conference of the International Joseph Alois Schumpeter Society (ISS) for helpful feedback. I especially thank Zakaria Babutsidze, Andreas Chai, and two anonymous referees for their insights.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cooper, K.B. Consumer well-being in a future of accelerating novelty. J Evol Econ 27, 315–335 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-015-0420-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-015-0420-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation