Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Industry dynamics, technological regimes and the role of demand

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we propose an industrial dynamics model to analyze the interactions between the price-performance sensitivity of demand, the sources of innovation in a sector, and certain features of the corresponding pattern of industrial transformation. More precisely, we study market concentration in different technological regimes and demand conditions. The computational analysis of our model shows that market demand plays a key role in industrial dynamics. Thus, although for intermediate values of the price-performance sensitivity, our results show the well-known relationships in the literature between technological regimes and industry transformation, we find surprising outcomes when demand is strongly biased either towards price or performance. Hence, for different technological regimes, a high performance sensitivity of demand tends to concentrate the market. On the other hand, under conditions of high price sensitivity, the industry generally tends to atomize. That is to say, for extreme values of the price-performance sensitivity of demand, we find concentrated or atomized market structures no matter the technological regime we are in. These results highlight the importance of considering the role of demand in the analysis of industrial dynamics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We use physical capital as numerary.

  2. See Ariga et al. (1999) for interesting empirical evidence on market shares as determinants of firms’ mark-ups.

  3. We make this simplifying assumption to focus on the analysis of the market competitive process. In Almudi et al. (2012) we consider growth and analyze its effects on industrial dynamics.

  4. 4 That is, there is a constant stock of physical capital K = 1, and we suppose that firms hire the capital they need to satisfy demand at any given moment. So, if a firm gains market share, it will hire additional units of capital, but if it loses share, it will stop hiring those units it no longer needs. Moreover, as \(Q=\Sigma Q_{jt}\) and \(K=\Sigma K_{jt}\), it is clear that, \(s_{it} \equiv \frac {Q_{it}} {Q}=\frac {K_{it}} {K}\). Likewise, since \(Q=K\) = 1, it follows that \(s_{it} =Q_{it} =K_{it}\).

  5. Where, \(\left \langle r \right \rangle =\left \{ {{\begin {array}{*{20}c} 0 & {r<0} \\ r & {0\le r\le 1} \\ 1 & {1<r} \\ \end {array}} } \right \}\)

  6. We are grateful for the referees’ comments regarding cumulativeness in Eq. 10. Although we shall concentrate on the case of high cumulativeness, an exhaustive exploration of the role of \(\eta \in [{0,1}]\) opens up lines for future research. To illustrate this point, we will explore some aspects of our model related to low cumulativeness in Section 4.1.2 and in the Appendix 2.

  7. Another extension of our model would involve introducing a parameter in Eq. 10 to control the impact of the success-breeds-success mechanism in R&D funding. We are also grateful to the referees for this suggestion. We shall leave this extension for future research, since it implies reflecting on the R&D to size relationship, or the possible existence of diminishing returns to R&D. See Klepper (1996) or Cohen and Klepper (1996).

  8. The minimum capital in our computational experiments is 10\(^{-6}\).

  9. Every time a firm enters or exits the market, the sum of all capitals is normalized to 1.

  10. Let us point out the importance of differentiating between barriers to imitation and technical entry barriers. Thus, (e.g.) in the aircraft-engine industry we find high technical entry barriers, together with low barriers to imitation (Marsili 1999).

  11. Our concept of stationarity implies that \(s_{it}\) = \(s_{it+1}\) and \(r_{it}=r_{it+1}\), for all i = 1, …, n and for all t.

  12. Let us remember that throughout our work, in general, we will suppose high cumulativeness in Eq. 10, that is, \(\eta \) \(=\) 1.

  13. All our simulation results can be replicated using the applet provided at: http://luis.izqui.org/models/indyterrod. By running this applet, the reader can easily check that the stationary distributions we report in this paper emerge regardless of the initial conditions. That is, neat patterns for the limiting distributions emerge, which depend on the specific parametric settings, but not on the departure point.

  14. These processes can be reproduced by using the applet: http://luis.izqui.org/models/indyterrod.

  15. The results of Appendix 2 show that, regarding low cumulativeness, the creative destruction character holds perfectly in the dynamics. With a provisional rough approximation, we can see that the cumulativeness parameter does not seem to have an excessive effect on the limit results in this case (see Appendix 2 and Fig. 5). However, future research should offer an exhaustive analysis of the role of cumulativeness in the model.

  16. See applet in: http://luis.izqui.org/models/indyterrod.

  17. Although the level of concentration decreases for the case of very low technological opportunities and very low entry barriers, we should ask ourselves whether it is realistic to consider a sector which innovates very little in product and where demand is very performance sensitive. This special case is probably the least relevant one from an empirical point of view.

  18. Not only for the high number of simulations required for a rigorous analysis of a stochastic model like ours, but also—and fundamentally—for the difficulties associated to the global treatment of the information and the extraction of conclusions from our simulations.

References

  • Almudi I, Fatas-Villafranca F, Izquierdo LR (2012) Innovation, catch-up and leadership in science-based industries. Ind Corp Change 21(2):345–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ariga K, Ohkusa Y, Nishimura KG (1999) Determinants of individual-firm markup in Japan: market concentration, market shares and FTC regulations. J Jpn Int Econ 13(4):424–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan T, Yin P (2010) Reallocating innovative resources around growth bottlenecks. Ind Corp Change 19(5):1589–1627

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Malerba F, Orsenigo L (2000) Technological regimes and schumpeterian patterns of innovation. Econ J 110:388–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen W, Klepper S (1996) A reprise of size and R&D. Econ J 106(437):925–951

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G (1988) Sources, procedures and microeconomic effects of innovation. J Econ Lit 26:1120–1171

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G (2001) Innovation, organization and economic dynamics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Nelson RR (2010) Technical change and industrial dynamics as evolutionary processes. In: Hall BH, Rosenberg N (eds) Handbook of the economics of innovation. Elsevier, North-Holland

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Marsili O, Orsenigo L, Salvatore R (1995) Learning, market selection and the evolution of industrial structures. Small Bus Econ 7(6):411–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fatas-Villafranca F, Saura D (2004) Understanding the demand-side of economic change. Econ Innov New Technol 13(8):695–716

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fatas-Villafranca F, Jarne G, Sanchez-Choliz J (2009) Industrial leadership in science based industries. J Econ Behav Organ 72(1):390–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fatas-Villafranca F, Saura D, Vazquez FJ (2011) A dynamic model of public opinion formation. J Public Econ Theory 13(3):417–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (1996) Entry, exit, growth and innovation over the product life cycle. Am Econ Rev 86(3):562–583

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S, Malerba F (2010) Demand, innovation and industrial dynamics: an introduction. Ind Corp Change 19(5):1515–1520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (2006) Innovation and the evolution of industries. J Evol Econ 16:3–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (2007) Innovation and the dynamics and evolution of industries. Int J Ind Organ 25:675–699

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (1993) Technological regimes and firm behavior. Ind Corp Change 2:45–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (1996) Schumpeterian patterns of innovation are technology-specific. Res Policy 25:451–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marsili O (1999) Technological regimes: theory and evidence. Dynacom Working Paper. http://www.lem.sssup.it/Dynacom/files/D20_0.pdf

  • Marsili O (2001) The anatomy and evolution of industries: technological change and industry dynamics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe JS (1998) Evolutionary economics and creative destruction. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (1982) The role of knowledge in R&D efficiency. Q J Econ 97(3):453–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pavitt K, Robson M, Townsend J (1989) Technological accumulation, diversification and organisation in UK companies, 1945–1983. Manag Sci 35:81–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98(5):71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg N (1976) Perspectives on technology. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg G, Verspagen B (2005) Evolutionary theorizing on economic growth. In: Dopfer K (ed) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ (1986) Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Res Policy 15:285–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (1984) Schumpeterian Competition in alternative technological regimes. J Econ Behav Organ 5:287–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (1987) Knowledge and competence as strategic assets. In: Teece DJ (ed)The competitive challenge. Strategies for industrial innovation and renewal. Ballinger Publishing Company, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Isabel Almudi.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Statement  In the deterministic version of the model (i.e. \(u_{\textrm Max}\) \(=\) \(\sigma \) \(=\) 0 and \(\lambda \) \(=\) 1), stationarity (i.e. \(s_{it}=s_{it+1}\) and \(r_{it}=r_{it+1}\), for all i and for all \(t)\) implies that all firms present in the market end up becoming indistinguishable from each other. Specifically, using \(n >\) 1 to denote the number of firms present in the market, in the long run (i.e. as time goes to infinity):

  1. (a)

    \(s_{it}=s_{i}\) \(=\) 1/n, \(\forall i\).

  2. (b)

    \(r_{it}=r_{i}=r\), \(\forall i\).

  3. (c)

    \(c_{it}=c_{i}=n\) /(\(n-r)\), \(\forall i\).

  4. (d)

    \(p_{it}=p_{i}\) \(=\) (n +1)/(\(n-r)\), \(\forall i\).

  5. (e)

    \(R_{it}=R_{i}=r\)/(\(n(n-r))\), \(\forall i\).

  6. (f)

    \(x_{it}=x_{i}=x^{\textrm Max}\), \(\forall i\).

(The case where there is only one firm in the market is insignificant).

Proof

The proof is conducted in several steps:

  1. 1.

    \(r_{it+1}=r_{it}\), \(\forall i\), \(\forall t\) \(\Rightarrow \) {Eq. 8}\(\Rightarrow \) \(r_{it}=r\), \(\forall i\), \(\forall t\).

  2. 2.

    \(s_{it+1}=s_{it}\), \(\forall i\), \(\forall t\) \(\Rightarrow \) {Eq. 5}\(\Rightarrow \) \(\gamma _{it} =\overline \gamma _t \), \(\forall i\), \(\forall t\).

  3. 3.

    \(c_{it} = 1 + \frac {R_{it}}{s_{it}} = 1 + {r_{it-1}} {\pi _{it-1}} \frac {s_{it-1}}{s_{it}} = 1 + {r_{it-1}} {s_{it-1}} {c_{it-1}} \frac {s_{it-1}}{s_{it}} = \{{{s_{it}} = s_{it-1} = {s_i} ;\;{r_{it}} =r} \}=1+r\cdot {s_i} \cdot {c_{it-1}}\)

Noting that \(r\cdot s_{i}<\) 1, we can solve the recursive equation to obtain:

$$c_{it} ={\left({1-\left({r\cdot s_i}\right)^t}\right)}/{\left({1-r\cdot s_i}\right)}+c_{i0} ({r\cdot s_i})^t $$

Thus, taking limits when t goes to infinity:

$$\lim\limits_{t\to \infty} c_{it} =1 / {( {1-r\cdot s_i} )}=c_i $$
  1. 4.

    \(R_{it+1} =r\cdot s_i^2 \cdot c_{it} \) \(\Rightarrow \) \(\lim \limits _{t\to \infty } R_{it} ={r\cdot s_i^2} / {( {1-r\cdot s_i} )}=R_i \).

  2. 5.

    \(p_{it} =( {1+s_i} )c_{it} \) \(\Rightarrow \) \(\mathop {\lim }\limits _{t\to \infty } p_{it} ={( {1+s_i} )} / {( {1-r\cdot s_i} )}=p_i \).

Also, note that, for all i, the convergence of prices \(p_{it}\) to the corresponding limit \(p_{i}\) is monotonous, and the series \(\vert p_{it}-p_{i}\vert \) is geometric and monotonously decreasing (remember that \(r\cdot s_{i} <\)1):

$$| {p_{it} -p_i} |=\left|({1+s_i})\;\left[c_{i0} -1 / {({1-r\cdot s_i})}\right] \right|({r\cdot s_i})^t $$

In simple words, prices stabilize, i.e. for any time h:

$$| {p_{ih+1} -p_{ih}} |>| {p_{it+1} -p_{it}} |\quad \quad \quad \forall t>h. $$
  1. 6.

    \(\gamma _{it} =\overline \gamma _t , \quad \forall i\), \(\forall t\) \(\Rightarrow \) \(\gamma _{it} =\gamma _{jt} \), \(\forall i\), \(\forall j\), \(\forall t\)

Therefore:

$$ \begin{array}{rll} \gamma_{it} &=&( {1-\alpha} )\frac{x_{it} -\overline x_t} {\overline x_t} -\alpha \frac{p_{it} -\overline p_t} {\overline p_t} =( {1-\alpha} )\frac{x_{jt} -\overline x_t} {\overline x_t} -\alpha \frac{p_{jt} -\overline p_t} {\overline p_t} =\gamma_{jt} \\ &&( {1-\alpha} )\frac{x_{it} -x_{jt}} {\overline x_t} =\alpha\frac{p_{it} -p_{jt}} {\overline p_t}\\ &&x_{it} -x_{jt} =\overline x_t \frac{\alpha} {1-\alpha} \frac{p_{it}-p_{jt}} {\overline p_t} \end{array} $$

Since \(x_{it} >\) 0, \(\forall i\), \(\forall t\), the equation above implies that beyond a certain time T (i.e. when prices stabilize and there are no changes in the ranking of prices anymore—see point 5 of the proof) there cannot be changes in the ranking of performances either, i.e. \(\exists T\) such that \(x_{iT} > x_{jT}\) \(\Rightarrow \) \(x_{it} > x_{jt}\), \(\forall t > T\). Thus:

\(\exists m\), T, such that \(x_{mt} =x_t^{\text {Max}} \), \(\forall t > T\). Using Eq. 10, this implies that \(x_t^{\text {Max}} =x^{\text {Max}}\), \(\forall t > T\).

Using Eq. 10 again, and noting that \(\mathop {\lim }\limits _{t\to \infty } R_{it} ={r\cdot s_i^2} / {( {1-r\cdot s_i} )}=R_i\) and that \({\phi \cdot r\cdot s_i^2} / {( {1-r\cdot s_i} )}<1\) (since there cannot be changes in the ranking of performances \(\forall t > T)\), it can be proved that:

$$\mathop{\lim}\limits_{t\to \infty} x_{it} =x^{\text{Max}} $$

Thus, in the long run: \(x_{it}=x_{i}=x^{\textrm Max}\), \(\forall i\). Bearing in mind also that in the long run \(\gamma _{it} =\overline \gamma _t \), we then obtain \(p_i =\overline p \), \(\forall i\). Thus:

$$ \begin{array}{rll} p_i &=& {( {1+s_i} )} / {( {1-r\cdot s_i} )}={( {1+s_j} )} / {( {1-r\cdot s_j} )}=p_j \\ &\Rightarrow & \quad {\{}0 < s_{i} < 1{\}} \quad \Rightarrow \quad s_i =s_j =s=1 / n, \forall i, j. \end{array} $$

Substituting this last result in the equations derived above, we obtain the 6 propositions (a–f) included in the statement. □

Appendix 2

Given the difficulties involved in an exhaustive computational analysis for all the parameters of the model,Footnote 18 we have taken high cumulativeness in Eq. 10 as an almost permanent assumption. However, it seems reasonable to check—even if only provisionally—what would happen to the patterns which emerge from entrepreneurial regimes, if we suppose low cumulativeness.

In Fig. 10 we present the results obtained for the Herfindhal index and the number of firms at t \(=\) 30,000, for the case of entrepreneurial regimes with \(\eta \) \(=\) 0.1, considering the level of technological opportunities is medium, and the demand has an intermediate profile. This parametric configuration allows us to directly compare Fig. 10 with Fig. 5, and thus see how the results change when considering low cumulativeness in entrepreneurial regimes.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Box-plots of the Herfindhal index (above) and the number of firms (below) at time step 30,000, for \(\alpha \) \(=\) 0.5, \(\lambda \) \(=\) 0.1, \(\phi \) \(=\) 0.9, \(u_{\textrm Max}\) \(=\) 0.5, \(\eta \) \(=\) 0.1 and different values of \(\sigma \) and \(\beta \). Each box-plot represents data from 1,000 simulation runs

As we can see in both figures, the expected results are maintained for the case of low cumulativeness. In this case, we also obtain low levels of industry concentration and a high number of firms in the limit states. This reinforces the results seen in Section 4.1.2 regarding the appearance of creative destruction patterns in entrepreneurial regimes.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Almudi, I., Fatas-Villafranca, F. & Izquierdo, L.R. Industry dynamics, technological regimes and the role of demand. J Evol Econ 23, 1073–1098 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0303-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0303-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation