Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Complexity and technological change: knowledge interactions and firm level total factor productivity

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The analysis of social interactions as drivers of economic dynamics represents a growing field within the economics of complexity. Social interactions are a specific form of interdependence whereby the changes in the behavior of other agents affect utility functions for households and production functions for producers. In this paper, we apply the general concept of social interactions to the area of the economics of innovation and we articulate the view that knowledge interactions play a central role in the generation of new technological knowledge so that innovation becomes the emergent property of a system, rather than the product of individual actions. In particular, we articulate and test the hypothesis that different layers of knowledge interactions play a crucial role in determining the rate of technological change that each firm is able to introduce. The paper presents an empirical analysis of firm level total factor productivity (TFP) for a sample of 7,020 Italian manufacturing companies observed during the years 1996–2005. This will enable us to identify the distinctive role of regional, inter-industrial and localized intra-industrial knowledge interactions as distinctive and significant determinants, together with internal research and innovation efforts, of changes in firm level TFP.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We acknowledge that entry can exert a relevant impact on innovation and technological change at the industry level. As witnessed by Aghion et al. (2004), a non-negligible share of productivity growth of incumbents can be attributed to an enhancing effect exerted by (foreign) entrants. This is true under the assumption that entrants immediately locate at the technological frontier. This amounts to an emphasis on the role of incumbents with respect to entrants: this seems consistent with the basic intuition that the decision to innovate is made according to the expectations about the behavior of competitors. However, the core research question in this paper addresses the role of regional and cognitive proximity in shaping knowledge interactions that affect the generation of new technological knowledge. Nevertheless, we recognize that the inclusion of market entry will be a relevant future extension of our analysis tacking an even broader set of research questions.

  2. Industries are defined according to the Italian classification system ATECO. We have adopted a three-digit level. In some circumstances, we had to aggregate data at two-digit level in order to have a sufficient number of firms for a statistically significant identification of the parameters of production functions.

  3. The level of yearly depreciation of physical capital has been chosen following the approach applied in previous studies that have applied perpetual inventory techniques to estimate yearly fixed capital levels adopting depreciation parameters in the range 5–10 % for physical capital.. Since the adopted depreciation parameter is constant across industries, we should not expected changes in the significance of estimate coefficients for slight changes in δ.

  4. R&D expenditures are the traditional indicator used to measure the amount of efforts to generate new technological knowledge. Actually, R&D statistics measure only a partial amount of the overall effort that firms make to introduce new technologies. Internal learning activities are not accounted for, nor is the cost to access external knowledge. Moreover the actual efficiency of the research activities is not considered as, of course, R&D activities only measure partially some inputs into the process. Additional issues that are specific to the Italian institutional and empirical evidence need to be considered. The Italian manufacturing industry is characterized by the geographical clustering of many small firms in specialized industrial districts. There are only a few large firms that represent a minority by all viewpoints. Reliable statistical evidence on R&D expenditures is missing. Official R&D statistics are based upon data collected from only 2,200 agents (be they firms or research organizations). As a consequence, official R&D statistics provide a picture of the research activities conducted by a minor portion of the economic activity carried out in the country. Small firms do not reply to the detailed and time-consuming questionnaires that are used as the indispensable tool for the collection of R&D data that are not requested for the compilation of annual reports. Accountancy rules coupled with fiscal allowances, however, provide excellent and reliable evidence upon stocks of intangible capital that include capitalized research expenditures as well as purchasing costs for patents and licences and the costs incurred to build and to implement brand and know how. It seems appropriate to rely upon the figures publicly available in all annual reports to get a reliable measure of the efforts to generate new technological knowledge.

  5. In the econometric analysis, we have used different definition for the indicator of intangible intensity, using both book values and perpetual inventory approaches with depreciation rates for intangible assets equal to 15 % and 20 %. Results are not significantly affected. In the paper, we present the results based on the yearly ratio of intangible to tangible assets based on book values.

  6. Following a consistent tradition in the applied econometrics of technological spillovers, we rely on data at the firm level, taking into account the main location of each firm (Mairesse and Cuneo 1985; Cincera 1997). This procedure is consistent with the empirical evidence considered: the dataset is based on information extracted from the annual reports of single companies. The average size is small. Multi-plant companies usually operate the different units by means of different legal identities. Hence, each unit of information can be considered mono-plant.

References

  • Aghion P, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P, Prantl S (2004) Entry and productivity growth: evidence from microlevel panel data. J Eur Econ Assoc 2:265–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli C (2007) The system dynamics of collective knowledge: from gradualism and saltationism to punctuated change. J Econ Behav Organ 62:215–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli C (2008a) Localized technological change. Towards the economics of complexity. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli C (2008b) Pecuniary knowledge externalities: the convergence of directed technological change and the emergence of innovation systems. Ind Corp Chang 17:1049–1070

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli C (ed) (2011) Handbook on the economic complexity of technological change. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli C, Scellato G (2011) Out of equilibrium profits and innovation. Econ Innov N Technol 20:405–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1962) Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: Nelson RR (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity: Economic and social factors. Princeton University Press for N.B.E.R, Princeton, pp 609–625

  • Arthur WB (2009) The nature of technology. The Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur WB, Durlauf SN, Lane DA (1997) Introduction. In: Arthur WB, Durlauf SN, Lane DA (eds) The economy as an evolving complex system II. Addison-Wesley, Reading, p 14

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB, Feldman M (1996) Spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. Am Econ Rev 86:630–640

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1991) A note on restaurant pricing and other examples of social influences on price. J Polit Econ 99:1109–1116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boschma RA (2005) Proximity and innovation: a critical assessment. Reg Stud 39:61–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Lissoni F (2003) Knowledge spillovers and local innovation systems: a critical survey. Ind Corp Chang 10:975–1005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cincera M (1997) Patents R&D and technological spillovers at the firm level: some evidence from econometric count models for panel data. J Appl Econ 12:265–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35:128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David PA (1993) Knowledge property and the system dynamics of technological change. In: Proceedings of the world bank annual conference on development economics. The World Bank, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Duguet E (2007) Innovation height spillovers and TFP growth at the firm level: evidence from French manufacturing. Econ Innov N Technol 15:415–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN (2005) Complexity and empirical economics. Econ J 115:225–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleming L, Sorenson O (2001) Technology as a complex adaptive system: evidence from patent data. Res Policy 30:1019–1039

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fransman M (2010) The new ICT ecosystem. Implications for policy and regulation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frenken K (2006) Technological innovation and complexity theory. Econ Innov N Technol 15:137–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehringer A (2011) Pecuniary knowledge externalities and innovation: intersectoral linkages and their effects beyond technological spillovers. Econ Innov N Technol 20:495–515

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser E, Scheinkman JA (2000) Non-market interactions, NBER Working Paper Series 8053

  • Glaeser E, Sacerdote B, Scheinkman JA (1996) Crime and social interactions. Q J Econ 109:507–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1957) Hybrid corn: An exploration in the economics of technological change. Econometrica 25:501–522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1992) The search for R&D spillovers. Scand J Econ 94:29–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso L, Schivardi F (2007) Spillovers in industrial districts. Econ J 117:68–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanusch H, Pyka A (2007) Principles of Neo-Schumpeterian economics. Camb J Econ 31:275–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1945) The use of knowledge in society. Am Econ Rev 35:519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV (1997) Externalities and industrial development. J Urban Econ 42:449–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs J (1969) The economy of cities. Jonathan Cape, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe AB (1986) Technological opportunity and spillover of R&D: evidence from firms’ patents, profits and market value. Am Econ Rev 79:985–1001

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe AB, Trajtenberg M, Henderson RM (1993) Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Q J Econ 108:577–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones BF (2009) The burden of knowledge and the death of the renaissance man: is innovation getting harder? Rev Econ Stud 76:283–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz ML, Shapiro C (1986) Technology adoption in the presence of network externalities. J Polit Econ 94:822–841

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane DA, Maxfield R (1997) Foresight complexity and strategy. In: Arthur WB, Durlauf SN, Lane DA (eds) The economy as an evolving complex system II. Westview Press, Santa Fe, pp 169–198

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane DA et al. (2009) Complexity perspectives in innovation and social change. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall B (1988) Innovation as an interactive process: from user-producer interaction to the national system of innovation. In: Dosi G et al. (eds) Technical change and economic theory. Frances Pinter, London, pp 349–369

    Google Scholar 

  • Mairesse J, Cuneo P (1985) Recherche-development et performances des entreprises: Une etude econometrique sur donnees individuelles. Rech Econ 36:100–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield E, Schwartz M, Wagner S (1981) Imitation costs and patents: an empirical study. Econ J 91:907–918

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manski CF (2000) Economic analysis of social interactions. J Econ Perspect 14:115–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manski CF (2003) Identification problems in the social sciences and everyday life. South Econ J 70:11–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (1959) The simple economics of basic scientific research. J Polit Econ 67:297–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1947) The creative response in economic history. J Econ Hist 7:149–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky T (1954) Two concepts of external economies. J Polit Econ 62:143–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel E (1998) Economies of product development by users: the impact of “sticky” local information. Manag Sci 44:629–644

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel V (1976) The dominant role of users in the scientific instrument innovation process. Res Policy 5:212–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (1996) Hybridizing growth theory. Am Econ Rev 86:207–212

    Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (1998) Recombinant growth. Q J Econ 113:331–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (1984) Schumpeterian competition in alternative technological regimes. J Econ Behav Organ 5:287–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge the financial support of the European Union D.G. Research with the Grant number 266959 to the research project ‘Policy Incentives for the Creation of Knowledge: Methods and Evidence’ (PICK-ME), within the context Cooperation Program / Theme 8 / Socio-economic Sciences and Humanities (SSH) in progress at the Collegio Carlo Alberto and the University of Torino, and the research assistance provided by Federico Caviggioli. Giuseppe Scellato acknowledges the funding of the Politecnico di Torino. Both authors acknowledge the comments of two anonymous referees and of the editor.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giuseppe Scellato.

Annex A

Annex A

Table 5 Robustness control
Table 6 Description of variables and summary statistics

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Antonelli, C., Scellato, G. Complexity and technological change: knowledge interactions and firm level total factor productivity. J Evol Econ 23, 77–96 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-012-0299-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-012-0299-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation