Skip to main content
Log in

Not invented here: technology licensing, knowledge transfer and innovation based on public research

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using a new dataset encompassing more than 2,200 inventions made by Max Planck Society researchers from 1980 to 2004, we explore the way in which inventor, technology, and licensee characteristics affect the commercialization of academic inventions. We find limited evidence suggesting that domestic and external licensees outperform foreign licensees and inventor spin-offs in the commercialization of academic inventions. Controlling for selection, spin-offs are indistinguishable from external licensees. Patented technologies and inventions by senior scientists are more likely to be licensed, but patent protection is related to lower commercialization odds and royalty payments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Patents may have an indirect effect on the assessment of individual performance in fields where the scientific community values patents (Owen-Smith and Powell 2001). Prior research indicates that, in some cases, Max Planck researchers pursue patenting activities primarily to enhance their standing in the respective communities.

  2. Before the “professors’ privilege” was abolished in 2002, the IPR regime in place at the Max Planck Society differed from that of German universities. University researchers used to be exempt from the law on employee inventions. They retained the intellectual property in their inventions (cf. Von Proff et al. 2012).

  3. Following failed attempts at constructing and marketing prototypes, in-house commercialization of Max Planck inventions was given up in the 1970s and was never taken up again.

  4. In this regard, Max Planck Innovation’s patenting policy thus appears to be closer to that of MIT than that of the UC system (cf. Shane 2002; Lowe and Ziedonis 2006).

  5. Researchers employed on a scholarship basis, mostly Ph.D. students and international postdocs, are not subject to the German law on employee inventions (Arbeitnehmererfindungsgesetz). To the extent that these individuals made inventions without other Max Planck researchers being involved, they do not show up in the data.

  6. Our invention data end in February 2005 and include six inventions disclosed early in 2005. In the subsequent analysis, these are merged into the group of 2004 inventions.

  7. In 141 cases, no patent information was found even though the inventions database identified them as patented. We suspect that most of these cases reflect cancelled applications. They are treated as not being patented in the subsequent analysis.

  8. This includes inventions coming out of temporary research groups and also, in a few cases, out of the Max Planck Society’s central administration.

  9. Patent ownership is a restrictive measure of collaborative invention (Fontana and Geuna 2009), which is reflected by the comparatively small number of collaborative inventions we thus identified. We alternatively considered using information about collaboration from the Max Planck Innovation invention database. However, since the database is updated regularly and we do not have information about when the collaboration information was entered, we did not use it in the analysis based on endogeneity concerns.

  10. In an unreported simple logit model of licensing (irrespective of licensee type), the patent indicator is significant at the 1% level.

  11. In an unreported simple logit model of licensing (irrespective of licensee type), the indicator of collaborative inventions is insignificant.

  12. To obtain propensity scores, a logit model for the likelihood of being licensed to a foreign licensee was estimated first. We use a specification similar to Model 2. Kernel-based matching of treated and untreated observations was then performed (cf. also Section 3). The common support condition is satisfied for all reported propensity score matching models.

  13. All unreported results are available from the authors upon request.

References

  • Agrawal A (2006) Engaging the inventor: exploring licensing strategies for university inventions and the role of latent knowledge. Strateg Manage J 27:63–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora A, Gambardella A (2010) Ideas for rent: an overview of markets for technology. Ind Corp Change 19:775–803

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azoulay P, Ding W, Stuart T (2009) The impact of academic patenting on the rate, quality and direction of (Public) research output. J Ind Econ 57:637–676

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belenzon S, Schankerman M (2009) University knowledge transfer: private ownership, incentives, and local development objectives. J Law Econ 52:111–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Lissoni F, Montobbio F (2008) University patenting and scientific productivity: a quantitative study of Italian academic inventors. European Management Review 5:91–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buenstorf G (2009) Is commercialization good or bad for science? Individual-level evidence from the Max Planck Society. Res Policy 38:281–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective of learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35:128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Nelson RR, Walsh JP (2002) Links and impacts: the influence of public research on industrial R&D. Manag Sci 48:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckhardt JT, Shane S, Delmar F (2006) Multistage selection and the financing of new ventures. Manag Sci 52:220–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elfenbein D (2007) Publications, patents, and the market for university inventions. J Econ Behav Organ 63:688–715

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fontana R, Geuna A (2009) The nature of collaborative patenting activities. Bocconi University, mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallini NT, Wright BD (1990) Technology transfer under asymmetric information. RAND J Econ 21:147–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall BH, Ziedonis RH (2001) The patent paradox revisited: an empirical study of patenting in the U.S. semiconductor industry, 1979–1995. RAND J Econ 32:101–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D, Scherer FM, Voper K (2003) Citations, family size, opposition and the value of patent rights. Res Policy 32:1343–1363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47:153–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ, Ichimura H, Todd P (1998) Matching as an econometric evaluation estimator. Rev Econ Stud 65:261–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henning E, Ullmann D (1998) Wissenschaftliche Mitglieder der Max-Planck-Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften im Bild. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe AB, Lerner J (2004) Innovation and its discontents. Princeton University Press

  • Jensen R, Thursby M (2001) Proofs and prototypes for sale: the licensing of university inventions. Am Econ Rev 91:240–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leuven E, Sianesi B (2003) PSMATCH2: Stata module to perform full Mahalanobis and propensity score matching, common support graphing, and covariate imbalance testing. http://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s432001.html

  • Levin RC, Klevorick AK, Nelson RR, Winter SG (1987) Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Pap Econ Act 1987(3):783–820

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lissoni F, Llerena P, McKelvey M, Sanditov B (2008) Academic patenting in Europe: new evidence from the KEINS database. Res Eval 17:87–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowe RA (2002) Entrepreneurship and information asymmetry: theory and evidence from the University of California. Carnegie Mellon University, mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowe RA (2006) Who develops a university invention? The impact of tacit knowledge and licensing policies. J Technol Transf 31:415–429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowe RA, Ziedonis AA (2006) Overoptimism and the performance of entrepreneurial firms. Manag Sci 52:173–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Max Planck Society (2000) Handbook of scientific members. Munich

  • Max Planck Society (2001) Start-up companies: guidelines for scientists of the Max-Planck-Gesellschaft. Munich

  • Max Planck Society (2002) Guidelines for knowledge and technology transfer. Munich

  • Max Planck Society (2008) Annual Report 2007. Munich

  • Mora-Valentin EM, Montoro-Sanchez A, Guerras-Martin L (2004) Determining factors in the success of R&D cooperative agreements between firms and research organizations. Res Policy 33:17–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mowery DC, Nelson RR, Sampat BN, Ziedonis AA (2001) The growth of patenting and licensing by U.S. universities: an assessment of the effects of the Bayh-Dole act of 1980. Res Policy 30:99–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray F, Stern S (2007) Do formal intellectual property rights hinder the free flow of scientific knowledge? An empirical test of the anti-commons hypothesis. J Econ Behav Organ 63:648–687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nooteboom B (1999) Innovation and inter-firm linkages: new implications for policy. Res Policy 28:793–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen-Smith J, Powell WW (2001) To patent or not: faculty decisions and institutional success at technology transfer. J Technol Transf 26:99–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phan PH, Siegel DS (2006) The effectiveness of university technology transfer. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship 2:77–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenbloom PR, Rubin DB (1983) The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects. Biometrika 70:41–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shane S (2002) Selling university technology: patterns from MIT. Manag Sci 48:122–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shane S, Stuart T (2002) Organizational endowments and the performance of university start-ups. Manag Sci 48:154–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (2000) Navigating the patent thicket: cross licenses, patent pools, and standard setting. Innov Policy Econ 1:119–150

    Google Scholar 

  • Sianesi B (2001) Implementing propensity score matching estimators with STATA. Prepared for the UK Stata Users Group, VII Meeting, London, May 2001

  • Stokes DE (1997) Pasteur’s Quadrant. Basic science and technological innovation. Brookings Institution Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ (1986) Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Res Policy 15:285–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ, Pisano G, Shuen A (1997) Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strateg Manage J 18:509–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen B (2006) University research, intellectual property rights and European Innovation Systems. J Econ Surv 20:607–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Proff S, Buenstorf G, Hummel M (2012) University patenting in Germany before and after 2002: what role did the professors’ privilege play? Industry and Innovation (in press)

  • Wooldridge JW (2002) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Max Planck Innovation GmbH for granting us access to their data. For helpful comments and discussions we thank Joerg Erselius, Astrid Giegold, Dietmar Harhoff, Bernhard Hertel, Evelyn Kaiser, Lionel Nesta, Alexander Schacht, Vangelis Souitaris and Dieter Treichel, as well as two anonymous reviewers. Wolfgang Ziegler and Sebastian Schmidt at the Patent Information Office of the University of Jena helped us assemble the patent database. Wolfhard Kaus provided valuable research assistance. This article is based on research done while both authors were at the Max Planck Institute of Economics. The usual caveat applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Guido Buenstorf.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Buenstorf, G., Geissler, M. Not invented here: technology licensing, knowledge transfer and innovation based on public research. J Evol Econ 22, 481–511 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0261-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0261-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation