Skip to main content
Log in

The origins of meso economics

Schumpeter’s legacy and beyond

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper starts from Schumpeter’s proposition that entrepreneurs carry out innovations (the micro level), that swarms of followers imitate them (meso) and that, as a consequence, ‘creative destruction’ leads to economic development ‘from within’ (macro). It is argued that Schumpeter’s approach can be developed into a new—more general—micro-meso-macro framework in economics. Center stage is meso. Its essential characteristic is bimodality, meaning that one idea (the generic rule) can be physically actualized by many agents (a population). Ideas can relate to others, and, in this way, meso constitutes a structure component of a ‘deep’ invisible macro structure. Equally, the rule actualization process unfolds over time—modelled in the paper as a meso trajectory with three phases of rule origination, selective adoption and retention—and here meso represents a process component of a visible ‘surface’ structure. The macro measure with a view to the appropriateness of meso components is generic correspondence. At the level of ideas, its measure is order; at that of actual relative adoption frequencies, it is generic equilibrium. Economic development occurs at the deep level as transition from one generic rule to another, inducing a change of order, and, at the surface level, as the new rule is adopted, destroying an old equilibrium and establishing a new one.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The concept of meso takes on an intermediate position in the distinction between micro and macro, and hence presumes that distinction. The micro-macro distinction became popular after the publication of Keynes’s General Theory, in which he demonstrated that the aggregates of individual decisions (micro) of a Walrasian or similar (neo-) ‘classical’ equilibrium was consistent with various states of the system when defined in terms of aggregates of other (macro) variables, in particular, employment, income and money volume. The present-day proponents of the so called “new” classical macro economics view the problem differently, but the important point here is that the established distinction between micro economics as dealing with Walras-type decision variables and macro economics as dealing with the mentioned aggregate variables has survived and is serving as a powerful taxonomic device and classifier for textbooks and teaching curricula in the discipline. This dichotomy did not exist at a time when Keynes was alive and when Schumpeter wrote his essay on Keynes. Schumpeter suggested calling “monetary analysis” or “income analysis” for what today is called macro economics, arguing that, “(s)ince the aggregates chosen for variables are, with the exception of employment, monetary quantities or expressions, we may also speak of monetary analysis, and, since national income is the central variable, of income analysis” (Schumpeter 1952/1997, 1997, p. 282). It is evident that the usage of the terms micro and macro economics is a mere convention and that we could employ with equal vindication Schumpeter’s terminology, or a similar one, to denote appropriately the distinction between the two sets of variables. Evolutionary economists see no necessity to follow the conventional terminology and usually refer, when talking about micro economic analysis, to firms, households or behavioral routines, and when talking about macro economic analysis to the division of labor and knowledge or static and dynamic relationships between aggregate magnitudes.

    The term ‘meso’ emerges as constituent concept, as we shall see, from an evolutionary perspective that defines micro and macro in this way. At this juncture, it is noteworthy that there is an impressive basket of all kinds of meso studies. The contributions to this large and growing research area include works on life cycles by Klepper (1997) and Grebel et al. (2006), on the entrepreneurial core of a meso-based economics Baumol (1968), on institutionally embedded Schumpeterian entrepreneurship Ebner (2002, 2010), on the co-evolutionary (technology-institution) dynamic by Nelson (2005), on modelling industrial evolution by Winter et al. (2003), on Schumpeterian competition by Winter (1984), on selective adoption and self-organization by Gowdy (1992), Foster (2000), and Knudsen (2002), on the historicity of industrial evolution by Malerba et al. (1999), on path dependence by David (2005), and Arthur (1989), on organization and innovation dynamics by Grebel (2009), Werker and Athreya (2004), Malerba (2006), Audretsch (1995), and Cordes (2005), on technical systems by Carlsson and Stankiewicz (1991), on heterogeneity, networks and industrial innovations by Cantner and Krüger (2004), Saviotti and Pyka (2008), Elsner (2010), and on methods and modelling building blocks Safarzyn’ska and van den Bergh (2010), to mention but a few from a rich set of important contributions.

  2. The term operant has been associated with a ‘Commodity Approach’. The term ‘generic’, in turn, shall denote the set of slow changing or ‘classical’ variables; these are typically kept constant in neoclassical economics.

    We are of course free to choose any term, but we think that the use of the stem ‘gen-’ has the advantage of embracing various meanings that are relevant for our analysis. The term ‘genetic’ is used in biology in reference to biological information, but we are interested only in the general aspect of information (gen), not in its biological specification (-etics, or gen-e). The stem ‘gen’ can be also associated with the terms ‘genesis’ or ‘generation’. The use of this meaning of the word stem is relevant for our analysis when dealing with change, for instance, when discussing the generation of novelty. While it would be sufficient to call this level simply X-level, we think that the neologism ‘generic’ can additionally provide a substantive meaning in that it can be associated in its stem generally with information, but also allows us to distinguish biological information (gene, genetic) from social and economic information (generic rule, generic analysis), and because the generality of the word stem allows us to include other relevant meanings, such as (rule) generation.

  3. The entropy law applied in its wider sense states that all physical phenomena follow an irreversible course from order to chaos; chaos denoting here non-order, without the predictive connotation of the chaos models. See Georgescu-Roegen (1971).

  4. For a more detailed discussion on the cortical areas and generic capabilities of Homo Sapiens Oeconomicus, see Dopfer (2005).

  5. For a rule approach, see Holland et al. (1986). Our unified rule approach resembles in many ways that of Holland, et. al. However, it differs in that it introduces a rule taxonomy distinguishing between subject rules (cognitive, behavioral) and object rules (social and technical organizational). It, further, introduces a multi-level (micro-meso-macro) co-evolutionary dynamic between the two with a view to explaining the static and dynamic of the economy as a whole. Rules and (rule) carriers are the primary analytical units of the generic level of the economic system.

  6. Veblen’s failure to provide any clear analytical exposition of the concept of cumulative causation has lead to its ignorance in the mainstream as well as in technically more sophisticated camps of heterodox economics, such as complexity theory or complexity economics.

    From a theoretical perspective it seems important to recognize that a close connection between Veblen’s approach and the concept of routines may be established. In their An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Nelson and Winter (1982) made a seminal contribution to economics by introducing Schumpeter’s concept of innovation and by developing it along Darwinian lines. However, unlike Schumpeter, they unpacked the intricate notion of innovation by suggesting the concept of routines. Their work gave rise to an enormous and still growing literature on routines, for instance, Lazaric and Raybaut (2005), Vromen (2004), Hodgson and Knudsen (2006), Cohendet and Llerena (2003), or, rediscovering Veblen along micro-meso-macro, Brette and Mehier (2008).

    We have introduced the canonical approach of rule, where rule has been defined as any idea with a deductive format for economic operations. The classic Nelson-Winter routine, or “organizational gene”, is a rule the carriers of which are subjects in a context that is organized by social and technical rules. A particularity of the term routine is that it refers, at least literally, to a completed process of routinization, or what Veblen called ‘habituation’. Human individuals are carriers of cognitive rules that allow them (if routinized) to perform operations in the ‘internal environment’ of the brain, and of behavioral rules that allow them (if routinized) to perform operations in the ‘external environment’ of social contexts. See, e.g. Ostrom (2004), Budzinski (2001), Dietrich (2006), Encinar and Munoz (2006), Dopfer and Potts (2008).

  7. The generic architecture proposed gives the notion of relative frequency a dual meaning. First, referring to process, it can be conceived as relative meso frequency, and second, referring to structure, as relative macro frequency. The issue of relative frequency and its significance for economics has been thoroughly analyzed by Metcalfe (1998, 2002), Metcalfe et al. (2006).

  8. There exists arguably still no coherent ‘evolutionary macro economics’ today. However, there is available a number of works that head exactly into that direction. These include for instance a study by Metcalfe et al. (2006) which links self-organization and self-transformation and explains the macro dynamic as emergent property of micro diversity and of meso change. In evolutionary growth models, self-organization and structure are dealt with in a dynamic context (unlike in neoclassical endogenous growth models). Contributions include works by Saviotti and Pyka (2008), Kwasnicka and Kwasnicki (2006), Silverberg and Verspagen (2005), Llerena and Lorentz (2004), Peneder (2004), and Alcouffe and Kuhn (2004), Fagerberg (2003), Verspagen (2002), Foster (1987, 2000).

    Other important building blocks of a macro theory refer to the division of knowledge and labor. Building on the legacy of Smith, Petty, Babbage and Storch, recent contributions include works by Leijonhufvud (1995), Loasby (1999), Metcalfe (2002), Helmstädter (2003), Antonelli (2008), Amendola and Gaffard (2003), and Foray (2004), as well as to issues of (macro) distribution, e.g. global distribution by Pyka et al. (1999).

    These works are paralleled by developments in agent-based modelling, in which agents are taken to be a bundle of data and behavioral methods, and the objective is to generate particular classes of macro regularities from particular classes of repeated interactions of agents. In the received taxonomy, this will be micro economics, but, considering that the models include all agents, all transactions and all reallocation outcomes of an economy, these and related models may well be conceived as ‘macro’ economics. The question to be settled is this: how much aggregation do we require for calling an analysis as belonging to macro economics? Contributions to this growing field include works by Pyka and Fagiolo (2005), Tesfatsion (2002), or Bandini et al. (2004).

References

  • Arthur WB (1989) Competing technologies, increasing returns and lock-in by historical events. Econ J 394:116–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alcouffe A, Kuhn T (2004) Schumpeterian endogenous growth theory and evolutionary economics. J Evol Econ 14:223–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amendola M, Gaffard J-L (2003) Persistent unemployment and co-ordination issues: an evolutionary perspective. J Evol Econ 13(1):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen ES (2009) Schumpeter’s evolutionary economics: a theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the engine of capitalism. Anthem, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli C (2008) Localised technological change. Towards the economics of complexity. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB (1995) Innovation and industry evolution. MIT, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandini S, Manzoni S, Vizzari G (2004) Multi-agent approach to localization problems: the case of multilayered multi agent situated systems. Web Intelligence and Agent Systems: An International Journal 2(3):155–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol W (1968) Entrepreneurship in economic theory. Am Econ Rev 58(2):64–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Brette O, Mehier C (2008) Building on the ‘micro-meso-macro’ evolutionary framework: the stakes for the analysis of clusters of innovation. In: Elsner W, Hanappi H (eds) Advancements in evolutionary institutional economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Budzinski O (2001) Cognitive rules and institutions—on the interrelation of intrapersonal and interpersonal rules. Universität Hannover Discussion Paper 241

  • Cantner U, Pyka A (2001) Classifying technology policy from an evolutionary perspective. Res Policy 30(5):759–775

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantner U, Krüger J (2004) Empirical tools for the analysis of technological heterogeneity and change, some basic building blocks of ‘evolumetrics’. Jenaer Schriften zur Wirtschaftswissenschaft 6/2004

  • Cantner U, Graf H (2008) Interaction structures in local innovation systems. Jena Economic Research Papers 040–2008

  • Carlsson B, Stankiewicz R (1991) On the nature, function and composition of technical systems. J Evol Econ 1(2):93–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohendet P, Llerena P (2003) Routines and communities in the theory of the firm. Ind Corp Change 12(3):271–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cordes C (2005) Long-term tendencies in technological creativity—a preference-based approach. J Evol Econ 15(2):149–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsi M (1991) Division of labour, technical change and economic growth. Avebury, Aldershot

    Google Scholar 

  • David PA (2005) Path dependence in economic processes: implications for policy analysis in dynamical systems contexts. In: Dopfer K (ed) The evolutionary foundations of economics. CUP, Cambridge, pp 151–194

    Google Scholar 

  • Dietrich M (2006) The nature of the firm in an evolutionary context. Mimeo, Sheffield

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K (1993) The generation of novelty in the economic process: an evolutionary concept. In: Dragan JC, Seifert EK, Demetrescu MC (eds) Entropy and bioeconomics. Nagard, Milano, pp 130–153

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K (ed) (2001) Evolutionary economics: program and scope. Kluwer, Dortrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K (ed) (2005) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K, Potts J (2008) The general theory of economic evolution. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K, Foster J, Potts J (2004) Micro–meso–macro. J Evol Econ 14:263–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Marengo L, Fagiolo G (2005) Learning in evolutionary environments. Dopfer K (ed) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebner A (2002) Institutions and innovation in economic development: schumpeterian perspectives. PhD Thesis, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Frankfurt am Main: Goethe University Frankfurt

  • Ebner A (2010) Embedded entrepreneurship: the institutional dynamics of innovation. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Elsner W (2010) The process and a simple logic of ‘meso’. Emergence and the co-evolution of institutions and group size. J Evol Econ 20(3):445–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Encinar M-I, Munoz F-F (2006) On novelty and economics: Schumpeter’s paradox. J Evol Econ 16:255–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg J (2003) Schumpeter and the revival of evolutionary economics: an appraisal of the literature. J Evol Econ 13:125–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foray D (2004) The economics of knowledge. MIT, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster J (1987) Evolutionary macroeconomics. Allen & Unwin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster J (2000) Competitive selection, self-organisation and Joseph A. Schumpeter. J Evol Econ 10:311–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgescu-Roegen N (1971) The entropy law and the economic process. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gowdy JM (1992) Higher selection processes in evolutionary economic change. J Evol Econ 2(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grebel Th, Krafft J, Saviotti P (2006) On the life cycle of knowledge intensive sectors. Revue de l’OFCE, Special issue, pp 63–85

  • Grebel Th (2009) Technological change: a microeconomic approach to the creation of knowledge. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 20(4):301–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanusch H (ed) (1988) Evolutionary economics: applications of Schumpeter’s ideas. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanusch H, Pyka A (2007a) Principles of neo-schumpeterian economics. Camb J Econ 31(2):275–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanusch H, Pyka A (eds) (2007b) Elgar companion to neo-schumpeterian economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Helmstädter E (ed) (2003) The economics of knowledge sharing. A new institutional approach. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2006) The nature and units of social selection. J Evol Econ 16(5):477–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holland JH, Holyoak KJ, Nisbett PR, Thagard (1986) Induction. Processes of inference, learning and discovery. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (1997) Industry life cycles. Ind Corp Change 6:145–181

    Google Scholar 

  • Knudsen Th (2002) Economic selection theory. J Evol Econ 12(3):443–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwasnicka H, Kwasnicki W (2006) Evolutionary modelling and industrial structure emergence. Rennard J-Ph (ed) Handbook of research on nature inspired computing for economy and management. Idea Group Reference, Hershey

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazaric N, Raybaut A (2005) Knowledge, hierarchy and the selection of routines: an interpretative model with group interactions. J Evol Econ 15(4):393–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leijonhufvud A (1995) The individual, the market and the industrial division of labour. Mongardini I (ed) L’individuo e il mercato. Bulzoni editore, Rome, pp 61–78

    Google Scholar 

  • Llerena P, Lorentz A (2004) Cumulative causation and evolutionary micro-founded technical change: a growth model with integrated economies. Working papers of BETA 2004–08, Strasbourg

  • Loasby JB (1999) Knowledge, institutions and evolution in economics. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (2006) Innovation and the evolution of industries. J Evol Econ 16(1–2):3–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Nelson R, Orsinego L, Winter S (1999) History friendly models of industrial evolution: the computer industry. Journal of Industrial and Corporate Change 1:3–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin R, Sunley P (2006) Path dependence and regional economic evolution. Journal of Economic Geography 6(4):395–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathews JA (2002) Introduction: Schumpeter’s lost chapter. Ind Innov 9(1–2):1–6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe JS (1998) Evolutionary economics and creative destruction. Routledge, London and New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe JS (2002) Knowledge of growth and the growth of knowledge. J Evol Econ 12(1–2):3–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe JS, Foster J, Ramlogan R (2006) Adaptive economic growth. Camb J Econ 30(1):7–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (2005) Technology, institutions and economic growth. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2004) The working parts of rules and how they may evolve over time. Papers on Economics and Evolution, 0404, Max Planck Institute, Jena

  • Peneder M (2004) Tracing empirical trails of schumpeterian development. Cantner U, Dinopoulos E, Lanzilotti RF (eds) Entrepreneurship, the new economy and public policy. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Perlman M, McCann CR (1998) The pillars of economic understanding, vol I, ideas and traditions. Michigan University Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Potts J (2000) The new evolutionary microeconomics: choice, complexity and adaptive behaviour. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Pyka A (2000) Informal networking and industrial life cycles. Technovation 20(11):25–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pyka A, Fagiolo G (2005) Agent-based modelling: a methodology for neo-schumpeterian economics. Discussion Paper no. 272, University of Augsburg

  • Pyka A, Cantner U, Krueger JJ (1999) Twin-peaks—what the knowledge-based approach can say about the dynamics of the world income distribution. Discussion Paper Series 189, Universität Augsburg, Institute of Economics

  • Rosenberg N (2000) Schumpeter and the endogeneity of technology: some american perspectives. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti P, Pyka A (2008) Micro and macro dynamics: industry life cycles: inter-sector coordination and aggregate growth. J Evol Econ 18(2):167–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Safarzyn’ska JC, van den Bergh JM (2010) Evolutionary models in economics: a survey of methods and building blocks. J Evol Econ 20(3):329–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1912/1926) Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1939) Business cycles: a theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper & Brothers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1952/1997) History of economic analysis. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Shionoya Y (1997) Schumpeter and the idea of social science: a metatheoretical study. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg G, Verspagen B (2005) Evolutionary theorizing on economic growth. In: Dopfer K (ed) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Stolper WF (1994) Joseph Alois Schumpeter. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Swedberg R (1991) Schumpeter: a biography. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Tesfatsion L (2002) Agent-based computational economics: growing economics from the bottom up. Artif Life 8:55–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen B (2002) Evolutionary macroeconomics: a synthesis between neo-Schumpeterian and neo-Keynesian lines of thought. Electron J Evol Model Econ Dyn. http://www.e-jemed.org/1007/index.php

  • von Hayek F (1937) Economics and knowledge. Economica IV(new ser):33–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Hayek F (1945) The use of knowledge in society. Am Econ Rev 35(4):519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Vromen JJ (2004) Routines, genes and program-based behaviour. Papers on Economics and Evolution, Max-Planck-Institute of Economics, 2004–20

  • Werker C, Athreya S (2004) Marshall’s disciples: knowledge and innovation driving regional economic development. J Evol Econ 14(5):505–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (1984) Schumpeterian competition in alternative technological regimes. J Econ Behav Organ 5:287–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG, Kaniovski Y, Dosi G (2003) A baseline model of industry evolution. J Evol Econ 13(4):355–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Witt U (2002) How evolutionary is Schumpeter’s theory of economic development. Ind Innov 9(1–2):7–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I gratefully acknowledge comments and suggestions by Georg D. Blind, Uwe Cantner, Richard Day, Peter Fleissner, John Foster, Jason Potts, Andreas Pyka, Mike Richardson, Markus Schwaninger, Ulrich Witt, and Charles R. McCann Jr.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kurt Dopfer.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dopfer, K. The origins of meso economics. J Evol Econ 22, 133–160 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0218-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0218-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation