Skip to main content
Log in

The role of domestic savings in outward-oriented growth strategies

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper presents a theory of technological catching-up in which local savings plays a key complementary role to international finance and foreign technology. Until now, the literature has primarily emphasized “outward orientation” as the key ingredient of catching-up success. It has indeed been argued that countries which have relied intensively on foreign technologies, either through capital goods imports or foreign direct investment inflows, have been successful while countries which have opted for inward-oriented growth strategy relying on domestic investment and import-substitution strategies have been unsuccessful. In this paper, we develop a sequential model of industrialization in which domestic savings is key to the success of outward-oriented growth strategies. Indeed, internal finance helps to overcome time-to-adjustment constraints which occur in the early phases of the catching-up process when both advanced foreign technologies and backward domestic ones co-exist. In this model, external finance, though international borrowing, and domestic savings are complementary, not substitutable, in the course of technological catching-up.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This renewal took place after the contribution by Baumol (1986) has strongly revived the debate on economic convergence.

  2. See Temple (1999) for a general overview on the so-called “new growth evidence.”

  3. Higher saving rates boost growth in both types of models because it implies higher capital accumulation. Accordingly, the traditional Solowian view tells us that a low-income country will converge faster, the higher is its saving rate. The modern AK view tells us that, everything else being equal, a country with a higher saving rate will permanently grow faster.

  4. In the Solow model, any source of external finance accelerates the convergence rate. In the Romer model, in contrast, opening small backward economies to international capital markets induces domestic savings to flow outside the economy, inducing global divergence. Neither of these extreme predictions are empirically consistent (For general discussions on the role of finance in AK-type models, see also Levine (1997) and Bellone and Dalpont (2003). More generally, the role of domestic savings for growth has remained a controversial empirical issue.

  5. This duration may correspond to the physical life of the process or to an optimal lifetime if one allows for truncation. It is the later assumption that will prevail in the model.

  6. CNR (1992) henceforth.

  7. Actually, this situation is closer to the actual position of Latin America and East European countries in the early 1960s than the situation of a subsistence economy.

  8. Subscript 1 refers to the production process operating in the developed environment of the RoW, which is supposed to operate on a steady-state growth path.

  9. Note that variables m and i are not given. They correspond to loan conditions prevailing for the RoW. It is possible to show that \(i = \hat r{\text{ and m = n}}_{\text{1}} {\text{ - }}k_1 \), where \(\hat r\) is the internal rate of return of the technique operated within the developed environment (see CNR (1992) for a proof).

  10. Empirical evidence show that the duration of production process is usually longer in developing countries compared to developed countries as the costs of maintenance (mainly labor costs) are lower in low-wage countries.

  11. The fixed wage assumption is appropriate to developing countries, at least in the early phases of industrialization, when large reserves of labor in rural areas exist which are ready to move to industrial areas for wages only slightly superior to those prevailing in the traditional agricultural sector. Usually, increasing pressure on real wage appears only later in the course of the catching-up process.

  12. Very specific assumptions regarding a 1(u) and a(u) flows would be required in order to guarantee that the relation between w and \(\hat w\) be such that \(r = \hat r\). Instead of making such peculiar assumptions, it will be supposed that there is no international mobility of capital assets. Then, even if the wage advantage endows the SOE with an effective return that is higher than the one prevailing in the RoW, firms of the RoW cannot take advantage of this occurrence by way of direct foreign investment. An alternative assumption could be that delocalization costs are high enough to destroy RoW firms’ incentives to invest their assets in the SOE.

  13. This assumption, known as the Full Performance hypothesis ( Hicks (1973), “Chapter V”), is explicited below.

  14. See CNR (1992) for a proof.

  15. It corresponds to the strongly forward biased technological change in the Hicksian classification.

  16. This simplifying assumption will be relaxed afterwards. Note that if n > n 1 Eq. 7 becomes: \(\int\limits_{t - \left( {n - k_1 } \right)}^{t - m} {q\left( {t + k_1 - u} \right)\,\;x\left( u \right)\,} du + \int\limits_{t - m}^t {\left[ {q\left( {t + k_1 - u} \right) - v} \right]\,\;x\left( u \right)\,} = C\left( t \right)\).

  17. See Hicks (1973, “Chapter V”) for a full description of the steady-state.

  18. Actually, another adjustment is likely to take place. Indeed, it might become profitable to truncate the domestic processes still in operation at time t = 0. This in turn will set free resources that will be used for initiating imported processes. For simplicity, however, this indirect effect of change is not considered here. See Belloc (1980) and Zamagni (1984) for an examination of this issue. This does not affect the economic meaning of the results to be presented below.

  19. Studying the late phase is then a matter of asserting under which conditions it is possible to prove the convergence of the traverse to the new steady-state g = sr. As Zamagni (1984, p. 148) points out however "what emerges from traverse theory is the substantial irrelevance of the problem of convergence as such. At best, the convergence of the late phase to a new equilibrium would take a long time and before the economy has entered the late phase and before that time has elapsed, a myriad of phenomena of various kinds would certainly have occurred to modify the basic relations of the economy.”

  20. See Eq. 6.0, p. 128 of Belloc (1980).

  21. The impact of changes in the savings behaviors in a neo-Austrian framework has already been conducted in other areas than development theory. See, in particular, Nardini (1993) and Amendola et al. (2001).

References

  • Abramovitz M (1986) Catching-up, forging ahead and falling behind. J Econ Hist XLVI(2):385−406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Comin D, Howitt P (2006) When does domestic savings matter for economic growth? NBER Working Paper No. 12275. NBER, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Amendola M, Gaffard JL (1988) The innovative choice. Basil Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Amendola M, Froeschle C, Gaffard J-L, Lega E (2001) Round-about production, co-ordination failure, technological change, and the wage-employment dilemma. J Econ Behav Organ Elsevier 46(1):1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (1986) Productivity growth, convergence, and welfare: what the long-run data show. Am Econ Rev 76:1072–1085

    Google Scholar 

  • Belloc B (1980) Croissance économique et adaptation du capital productif. Economica, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Bellone F, Dalpont M (2003) Does finance matter for growth? The new growth theory facing the East Asian “productivity puzzle”. In: Hagemann H, Seiter S (eds) New developments in growth theory and growth policy. Routledge, London, pp 40−62

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantalupi M, Nardini F, Ricottili M (1992) A development strategy with foreign borrowing: a neo-Austrian approach. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 3(2):201–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caroll CD, Overland J, Weil DN (2000) Savings and growth with habit formation. Am Econ Rev 90:341–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collins S, Bosworth B (1996) Economic Growth in East Asian: Accumulation versus Assimilation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2:135–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomulka S (1990) The theory of technological change and economic growth. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1991) Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg J (1987) A technology gap approach to why rates differ. Res Policy 16(2-4):87–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagerber J (1995) Convergence or divergence? The impact of technology on why growth rates differ. J Evol Econ 5(3):269–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks J (1973) Capital and time. Clarendon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (1997) Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda. J Econ Lit XXXV:688–726

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1993) Making a miracle. Econometrica 61(2):251–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nardini F (1993) Traverse and convergence in the neo-Austrian model: the case of a distributive shock. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 4(1):105−125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez F, Rodrik D (2000) Trade policy and economic growth: a skeptic’s guide to the cross-national evidence. In: Bernanke B, Rogoff KS (eds) Macroeconomics annual 2000. MIT for NBER, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1986) Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth. J Polit Econ, University of Chicago Press, vol. 94(5), pp 1002–1037

  • Solow RM (1956) A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Q J Econ 70:65–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz J (1996) Financial market, public policy and the East Asian miracle. World Bank Res Obs 11(2):249–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Temple J (1999) The new growth evidence. J Econ Lit 37(1):112–156

    Google Scholar 

  • Temple J, Johnson PA (1998) Social capability and economic growth. Q J Econ 113(3):965–990

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen B (1991) A new empirical approach to catching up and falling behind. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 2:359–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zamagni S (1984) Ricardo and Hayek effects in a fixwage model of traverse. Oxf Econ Pap 39:135–151

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Flora Bellone.

Appendix

Appendix

In order to compare the number of starts of new processes on the traverse path with those on the reference path, a variable that will represent the resulting gap is needed. Taking Eq. 8 and replacing \(C*\left( t \right)\) with its value \(\int\limits_{t - n}^t {q*\left( {t - u} \right)x*e^{gu} du} \), we obtain: \(\int\limits_{t - \inf \left( {t,n - k_1 } \right)}^t {q*\left( {t - u} \right)x*e^{gu} } du = \int\limits_0^t {\left[ {q\left( {t + k_1 - u} \right) - v} \right]x\left( u \right)du} \) which is equivalent to: \(\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\int\limits_{t - \inf \left( {t,n - k_1 } \right)}^t {\left[ {q\left( {t + k_1 - u} \right) - v} \right]x\left( u \right)du - \quad \int\limits_{t - \inf \left( {t,n - k_1 } \right)}^t {\left[ {q\left( {t + k_1 - u} \right) - v} \right]x^* e^{gu} du} } } \hfill \\ { = \int\limits_0^t {q^* \left( {t - u} \right)x^* e^{gu} du - \quad \int\limits_{t - \inf \left( {t,n - k_1 } \right)}^t {\left[ {q\left( {t + k_1 - u} \right) - v} \right]x^* e^{gu} du} \quad } } \hfill \\ \end{array} \)

Integrating by parts the left-hand side of the latter equation and transforming the right-hand side by a change in variable (u becomes t − u), we obtain a formulation that is akin to Eq. 9:

For t < n − k 1

$$Y\left( t \right) + \int\limits_0^t {\frac{{q\prime \left( {t + k_1 - u} \right)}}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}Y\left( u \right)du = \frac{1}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}\left( {\int\limits_0^t {\left[ {q*\left( u \right) - \left( {q\left( {u + k_1 } \right) - v} \right)} \right]x*e^{g\;\left( {t - u} \right)} du} } \right)} $$
(10)

For \(n - k_1 < t < n*\)

$$Y\left( t \right) + \int\limits_0^t {\frac{{q\prime \left( {t + k_1 - u} \right)}}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}Y\left( u \right)du = } \frac{1}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\int\limits_0^{n - k_1 } {\left( {q*\left( u \right) - \left[ {q\left( {u + k_1 } \right) - v} \right]} \right)x*e^{g\left( {t - u} \right)} du + } } \\ {\int\limits_{n - k_1 }^t {q*\left( u \right)x*e^{g\left( {t - u} \right)} du + q\left( {n - k_1 } \right)Y\left( {t - n + k_1 } \right)} } \\ \end{array} } \right)$$

This Volterra integral equation of the second kind has the same convolution kernel as Eq. 9. The unknown variable is Y(t) and we are, in fact, interested in is studying its sign. As the resolved kernel is positive, this study boils down to finding the sign of the right-hand side of Eq. 8. Indeed, by expressing the latter by h(t), we have:

$$Y\left( t \right) = h\left( t \right) + \int\limits_0^t {S\left( {t + k_1 - u} \right)h\left( u \right)du} $$

The expression of h(t) in Eq. 10 is:

$$h\left( t \right) = \left( {\int\limits_0^t {\frac{{\left[ {q*\left( u \right) - \left( {q\left( {u + k_1 } \right) - v} \right)} \right]}}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}x*e^{g\left( {t - u} \right)} du} } \right)$$

It is positive whatever t < n − k 1 and, thus, Y(t)>0 whatever t < n − k 1.

Moreover, we have \(h\prime \left( \tau \right) = gh\left( t \right) + \frac{{q*\left( t \right) - q\left( {k_{1 + t} } \right)}}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}x* > 0\quad \forall t < n - k_1 \) and, then, \(Y\prime \left( t \right) = x\left( t \right) - x*e^{gt} > 0\,\forall t < n - k_1 \).

For t ∈ [n − k 1, n*], h(t) takes another form:

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {h\left( t \right) = \frac{1}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}\int\limits_0^{n - k_1 } {\frac{{\left( {q*\left( u \right) - \left[ {q\left( {u + k_1 } \right) - v} \right]} \right)x*e^{g\left( {t - u} \right)} du}}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}} } \\ { + \int\limits_{n - k_1 }^t {\frac{{q*\left( u \right)x*e^{g\left( {t - u} \right)} du}}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}} + \frac{{q\left( {n - k_1 } \right)}}{{q\left( {k_1 } \right) - v}}Y\left( {t - n + k_0 } \right)} } \\ \end{array} $$

The two last terms of the right-hand side are negative. It is then possible that h(t), and consequently Y(t), becomes negative between t = n − k 1 and t = n*.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bellone, F. The role of domestic savings in outward-oriented growth strategies. J Evol Econ 18, 183–199 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-007-0083-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-007-0083-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation