Skip to main content
Log in

Agglomeration near and far, the case of Southern California: supply chains for goods and ideas

  • Special Issue Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Prosperity and economic growth require robust specialization and exchange. This means the formation and maintenance of numerous complex supply chains. These are emergent and include supply chains for things and supply chains for ideas. The former involve transactions; the latter can be via transactions and/or realized positive externalities. All supply chains have a geographic dimension which is also emergent. Firms carefully choose what to make vs what to buy and also where to sell or buy it, near or far. The whole system tends to be a pattern of locations that denote realized transactions (and transactions costs) as well as realized externalities. The city remains a competitive producer if these relationships are encouraged with the attendant costs contained. Cities are “engines of growth.” They offer attractive supply chain formation and management opportunities, including the various spatially situated supply chains for things and ideas. The latter are more complex than textbook discussions of non-rival goods suggest. People are keen to identify and acquire useful knowledge. Consider (1) the advantages of open-source knowledge sharing have been acknowledged; (2) ideas often denote complex tacit knowledge exchange, and (3) access to useful knowledge is priced in land markets and impacts location choice. Favorable networking and location opportunities are significant. Flexible land markets facilitate the availability of such opportunities. Access to pools of human capital is clearly beneficial, but the ability to tailor access to the peculiar requirements of the firm is even better. Detailed firm location data for various sectors for the Los Angeles metropolitan areas are analyzed to support our claims. We estimate Ripley k-functions and note differences by industry as well as firm size. There is agglomeration that is near as well as far. This finding complicates “death of distance” as well as “clustering” discussions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

(Source: Geographic Research, Inc., 2014)

Fig. 3

Source: “The geography of start-ups: something in the air: why birds of a tech feather flock together” The Economist, October 27, 2012

Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “Sustainable economic growth” is palpable and distinct from the widely cited but vague “sustainability.”

  2. Johansson and Quigley (2004) note that networks are akin to a club with insiders and outsiders, while agglomeration refers to situations where exclusion is difficult. Their paper develops differences and similarities. They also note that significant co-location denotes agglomeration, but many new networking options may accomplish as much but over a larger space. “We have seen that agglomeration economies and network economies are two different complementary ways of solving problems of market exchange” (p. 10). But supply chains, especially involving ideas, may or may not involve transactions.

  3. http://www.econlib.org/library/Essays/rdPncl1.html.

  4. “The most important consequence of specialization and trade is that we specialize in just a few tasks but we enjoy the products of millions of tasks.” http://www.arnoldkling.com/blog/formalize-this/.

  5. Jasanoff (2018) reminds us that it is best to consider “the continuum that unites the brain with its surroundings.” (p. 90). He explains that the brain cannot be separated from all else that goes on in the body. “Nowhere is the integration of brain and body more apparent than in the domain of our emotions.” (p. 98). “… the brain is an essential link in the causal chain that binds our internal biology to the environment around us; it is the great communicator that relays signals from the outside world into each person an back out again.” (p. 144).

  6. Wegner and Gray (2016) compare to colonies of individual ants; the former is much more capable than the latter. They refer to “emergence” which occurs when elements are “connected correctly” (p. 222–223).

  7. A useful survey of discussions that link tacit information, innovation and location is in Howells (2002).

  8. This view ignores the psychological reasons that people might give for actually avoiding information (Golman et al. 2017).

  9. At this writing, Google Scholar brings up 100,000 citations for “useful knowledge.”

  10. Some writers cite the underlying “chains of promises.” Ridley (2010) chose to be clearer, “I believe that at some point in human history, ideas began to meet and mate, to have sex with each other.” Random combinations of genes and ideas followed by competition and selection.

  11. “Networks are yet another IQ multiplier” (Jones 2015, p. 148).

  12. Choosing places to meet is increasingly important and even modeled. See, for example, Tilahun and Levinson (2009).

  13. Some authors prefer “internal agglomeration” economies, Alacazer and Delgado (2013).

  14. Much has been written about “smart growth” controls, but very little about a light touch approach that recognizes indispensable market signals. One exception is a paper by Staley and Scarlett (1977).

  15. Not long ago, some writers suggested the “death of distance” (Cairncross 2001). “Will improvements in information technology eliminate face-to-face interactions and make cities obsolete?” (Gaspar and Glaeser 1996, who cite many other such prognostications; they also note that the introduction of telephony did not interrupt the path of urbanization).

  16. See, for example, Gordon and Ikeda (2011) who question the value of the simple question.

  17. http://www.santafe.edu/research/cities-scaling-and-sustainability/.

  18. A large empirical literature supports this point. See, for example, Pollakowski and Wachter (1990).

  19. “After all, the most famous modern agglomeration of industry, Silicon Valley, has occurred in the industry with the most access to the latest and best information technology” (Gaspar and Glaeser 1996, p. 43). This is still true 20 years later.

  20. US Congress, Office of Technology Assessment. OTA (1995, p. 70).

  21. The regression sample size = 2991 because not all sector pairings exist in our study area.

  22. Ellison et al. (2010) also regress co-location correlations on plausible explanatory variables, but they consider only the manufacturing sectors.

  23. Glaeser (2000, p. 84).

  24. Success includes the ability to make substitutions if/when there are unreliable partners; bigger cities offer more choice opportunities.

  25. Glaeser and Scheinkman (2001) note that “Cities themselves are networks and the existence, growth and decline of urban agglomerations depend to a large extent on these interactions” (p. 427). I claim that supply chains for things and supply chains for ideas denote more than allusions to networks. With respect to the latter, we have more and better ideas when we function in an environment of smart and creative people. See Jones (2015). Within that environment, we work hard to discover and cultivate the best sources. Lee’s Entrepreneurial Supply Chains (2012) is distinct from what I refer to here.

  26. Garreau (1991, p. 29).

  27. Each of these is, of course, necessarily continuous. Such is competition. Maskell and Malmberg (1999).

  28. Some have cited Japanese zoning as more flexible. http://www.mlit.go.jp/common/000234477.pdf.

References

  • Alcácer J, Delgado M (2013) Spatial organization of firms and location choices through the value chain. Harvard Business School Working Paper 13–025

  • ArcGIS Pro (2017) Retrieved Aug 25, 2017 from http://pro.arcgis.com/en/pro-app/tool-reference/spatial-statistics/multi-distance-spatial-cluster-analysis.htm

  • Angel SS, Blei A (2015) Commuting and the Productivity of American Cities. New York University, Marron Institute of Urban Management

  • Bessen J (2015) Learning by doing. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulding KE (1966) The economics of knowldge and the knowledge of economics. Am Econ Rev 56(1/2):1–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Cairncross F (2001) The death of distance: how the communications revolution is changing our lives. Harvard Business School Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox W (2011) Constraints on housing supply: natural and regulatory. Econ J Watch 8(1):13–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Dennett DC (2017) From bacteria to bach and back. W.W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Desrochers P, Sautet F (2004) Cluster-based economic strategy, facilitation policy and the market process. Rev Aust Econ 17(2/3):233–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixon PM (2002) Ripley’s K function. In: El-Shaarawi AH, Piegorsch WW (eds) Encyclopedia of environmetrics, vol 3. Wiley, Chichester

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellison G, Glaeser EL, Kerr WR (2010) What causes industry agglomeration? Evidence from coagglomeration patterns. Am Econ Rev 100:1195–1213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman MA (1994) The geography of innovation. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Garreau J (1991) Edge city: life on the new frontier. Doubleday, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaspar J, Glaeser EL (1996) Information technology and the future of cities. NBER Working Paper 5562

  • Gelernter D (2016) The tides of mind: uncovering the spectrum of consciousness. Liveright Publishing, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser EL (2000) The new economics of urban and regional growth Ch 5. In: Clark GL, Feldman MP, Gertler MS (eds) The oxford handbook of economic geography. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser EL, Scheinkman JA (2001) Measuring social interactions. In: Durlauf S, Young P (eds) Social dynamics. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Golman R, Hagmann D, Loewenstein G (2017) Information avoidance. J Econ Lit 55(1):96–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon P, Ikeda S (2011) Does density matter? In: Andersson DE et al (eds) Handbook of creative cities. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1945) The uses of knowledge in society. Am Econ Rev 35(4):519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Howells JRL (2002) Tacit knowledge, innovation and economic geography. Urban Stud 39(5-6):871–884

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda S (2004) Urban interventionism and local knowledge. Rev Aust Econ 17:247–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jasanoff A (2018) Biological mind: how brain, body and environment collaborate to make us we are. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson B, Quigley J (2004) Agglomeration and networks in spatial economics. Pap Reg Sci 83(1):165–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones G (2015) Hive mind: how your nation’s IQ matters so much more than your own. Stanford University Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Laland KN (2017) Darwin’s unfinished symphony: how culture made the human mind. Princeton University Press, Princeton and London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lee WB (2012) Creating entrepreneurial supply chains. J. Ross Publishing Inc, Ft Lauderdale

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin MCY (2013) Talent migration: Does the importance of jobs and amenities change over migrants’ life course and the business cycle? Unpublished PhD dissertation, University of Southern California

  • Lucas RE Jr (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskell P, Malmberg A (1999) Localised learning and industrial competitiveness. Cambridge J Econ 23:167–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (2007) The market for ideas and the origins of economic growth in eighteenth century Europe. Tijdschrift Voor Sociale en Economische Geshiedenis 4:3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollakowski HO, Wachter SM (1990) The effects of land use constraints on housing prices. Land Econ 66(3):315–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridley M (2010) The rational optimist. Harper-Collins, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Saxenian AL (1996) Regional advantage: culture and competition in silicon valley and route 128. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Seabright P (2004) The company of strangers. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Staley S, Scarlett L (1977) Market-oriented planning: principles and tools. Reason Public Policy Institute, Policy Study, Los Angeles, p 236

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilahun N, Levinson D (2009) Contacts and meetings: location, duration and distance traveled. University of Minnesota, Department of Civil Engineering

  • U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment (1995) The technological reshaping of Metropolitan America, OTA-ETI-643. U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Wegner DM, Gray K (2016) The mind club: who thinks, what feels and why it matters. Viking, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank two anonymous referees and Dr. Sungbin Cho of the Southern California Association of Governments for valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter Gordon.

Appendix

Appendix

See Figs. 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20, 21, 22, 23, 24, 25, 26, 27, 28, 29, 30, 31, 32, 33 and 34.

Fig. 8
figure 8

a Sector 311, all firms, b sector 311, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 9
figure 9

a Sector 312, all firms, b sector 312, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 10
figure 10

a Sector 313, all firms, b sector 313, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 11
figure 11

a Sector 314, all firms, b sector 314, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 12
figure 12

a Sector 315 all firms, b sector 315: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 13
figure 13

a Sector 316 all firms, b sector 316: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 14
figure 14

a Sector 321 all firms, b sector 321: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 15
figure 15

a Sector 322 all firms, b sector 322: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 16
figure 16

a 323 all firms, b 323: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 17
figure 17

a Sector 324 all firms, b sector 324: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 18
figure 18

a Sector 325, all firms, b sector 325: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 19
figure 19

a Sector 326 all firms, b sector 326: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 20
figure 20

a Sector 327 all firms, b sector 327: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 21
figure 21

a Sector 331, all firms, b sector 331, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 22
figure 22

a Sector 332 all firms, b sector 332: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 23
figure 23

a Sector 333 all firms, b sector 333: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 24
figure 24

a Sector 334 all firms, b sector 334: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 25
figure 25

a Sector 335, all firms, b sector 335: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 26
figure 26

a Sector 336, all firms, b sector 336: # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 27
figure 27

a Sector 337, all firms, b sector 337, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 28
figure 28

a Sector 339, all firms, b sector 339, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 29
figure 29

a Sector 511, all firms, b sector 511, # of employment equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 30
figure 30

a Sector 512, all firms, b sector 512, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 31
figure 31

a Sector 515, all firms, b sector 515, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 32
figure 32

a Sector 517, all firms, b sector 517, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 33
figure 33

a Sector 518, all firms, b sector 518, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Fig. 34
figure 34

a Sector 519, all firms, b sector 519, # jobs equal or over 90th pctl

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gordon, P., Cho, J. Agglomeration near and far, the case of Southern California: supply chains for goods and ideas. Ann Reg Sci 61, 517–552 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-018-0881-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-018-0881-6

JEL Classification

Navigation