1 Introduction

Given the progressive population aging in developed countries, increasing female labor force participation (hereafter, LFP) and employment are paramount if Europe is to meet its 2020 target of 75% employment among those aged 20–64, a necessary objective for boosting economic growth and ensuring national pension system sustainability. Achieving this goal involves narrowing the employment gender gap, which to different degrees is still substantial in all EU member states but especially high in Southern European countries. In fact, a recent OECD (2012) analysis of labor market gender gaps reports 2011 male versus female employment rates in the 15–64 age group of 65.9 versus 45.1% in Greece, 64.1 versus 52.8% in Spain, and 67.5 versus 46.5% in Italy.

Although several explanations are proposed for the low labor force attachment of women in Southern European countries, the most cited are cultural influences like the “male breadwinner model” and institutional constraints (which, in turn, may also reflect cultural influences). Among the latter, the lack of publicly provided childcare is stressed as a major barrier to women’s reconciliation of family with career (Del Boca and Vuri 2007; Del Boca and Sauer 2009). In Italy, for instance, public expenditure on childcare accounts for a tiny 0.2% of GDP, which is half of the average OECD-30 expenditure (see Fig.x 1). Unfortunately, the need to cope with tight budgetary constraints after the Great Recession has prevented most Southern European countries from increasing the funds allocated to family policies and thus hampered any substantial progress in raising female employment. It is therefore likely that in a context of low or even shrinking public childcare provision, grandparents (and relatives in general) may serve as an important source of affordable childcare for working women. According to Hank and Buber (2009), for instance, about 32% of European grandmothers are engaged in regular childcare (i.e., almost weekly or more often) with percentages in countries such as Greece, Italy, and Spain almost twice as large as those in Scandinavia. In Italy, a survey run by the Italian National Statistical Institute (ISTAT) in 2005 shows that grandparents remain the main source of childcare when the mother is working. Among 1–2-year-old children of working mothers, about half (52.3%) are looked after by grandparents, 13.5% are enrolled in public nurseries, 14.3% in private nurseries, and 9.2% looked after by nannies (ISTAT 2005). In this paper, we assess whether grandparents’ potential availability for childcare, proxied by their meeting pension eligibility requirements, has a positive effect on female, and especially maternal, labor force participation.Footnote 1 This question is relevant not only in light of the widespread structural underinvestment in public childcare in many European countries, but also the recent pension reforms introduced in many EU member states. These reforms, by setting stricter retirement eligibility requirements, may have unintended consequences on female employment. For example, we show that raising retirement age and years of contributions, by reducing the supply of low-cost, flexible, informal childcare provided by grandparents, can reduce the labor force participation of mothers. Hence, pension reforms that are not coupled with sufficient investment in public childcare may further exacerbate the already wide intergenerational and gender gaps in employment by reducing the employment of young women relative not only to older women but also to young men, who traditionally bear less of the childcare burden.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Public expenditure on childcare and early education services, percent of GDP, 2011. Source: OECD Family Database (http://www.oecd.org/social/family/database.htm), chart PF3.1

The case of Italy is ideal for studying how changes in pension eligibility impact labor force participation because in recent years it has undergone several pension reforms that have gradually increased retirement requirements. For instance, whereas prior to 1992, the 20-year accumulated contribution rule allowed many public sector workers to retire in their 40s or early 50s, since then several pension reforms have gradually increased the number of years of contributions required for seniority-based retirement, and raised the minimum age required for age-based retirement to 65. These pension eligibility rules, which vary over time and according to such factors as gender and employment sector, provide an arguably exogenous variation (see also, Bottazzi et al. 2006; Battistin et al. 2009, 2015; Aparicio-Fenoll and Vidal-Fernandez 2015) used in this paper to identify the effect of grandparental childcare availability on maternal employment.

Our estimates show that mothers of cohabiting children under 15 whose own mothers are eligible for retirement have a 7.1 percentage point higher probability of labor force participation (+ 11%) than those whose mothers are not yet eligible. We interpret this result to mean that grandparental availability for childcare facilitates the labor force participation of women with young children. This interpretation is confirmed by the absence of any such effect for men or for women with no cohabiting children under 15, but a large effect for women with very young children, who have the most intensive childcare needs, and for low-educated mothers or mothers in small municipalities, who have fewer childcare alternatives available in the market. Our baseline results are also robust to several sensitivity checks; in particular, accounting for potential sample selection issues into having a cohabiting child aged 0–14, considering employment instead of LFP, and including controls for additional pathways through which grandparental retirement eligibility may affect female LFP (e.g., income and wealth transfers).

Our paper complements the evidence in Aparicio-Fenoll and Vidal-Fernandez (2015) by exploiting seniority-eligibility rules in addition to age-eligibility rules. This is a nonnegligible improvement because past research has shown that individuals tend to retire as soon as possible (Behaghel and Blau 2012; Gruber and Wise 2007), and reforms increasing age requirements may cause a “run to seniority pension” (Brugiavini and Peracchi 2012; Ardito 2017) increasing the relative incidence of seniority vis-à-vis old-age pensions. As a consequence, the age-eligibility rules exploited in previous papers are likely to be binding only for those grandparents who did not or could not use the seniority rules such as late labor market entrants (e.g., highly educated individuals), grandparents with very discontinuous working lives, or those who did not have to provide childcare (see Rupert and Zanella 2014). The potential endogeneity of individuals’ seniority-based eligibility is addressed (i) by controlling for a large set of determinants of grandparents’ retirement eligibility available in our data (age, gender, education, and employment sector and type), so that our preferred model is only identified by changes in the retirement rules mandated by pension reforms; and (ii) by not using grandparents’ actual years of pension contributions to compute seniority eligibility, but imputing years of contributions based on the average behavior of individuals with the same characteristics. Our results point to the importance of exploiting both sources of eligibility. Indeed, our estimated effects are substantially larger than the comparable (reduced form) estimates reported by Aparicio-Fenoll and Vidal-Fernandez (2015), especially on the sample of women with younger children (− 15 percentage point vs. − 3 percentage point). This difference leads to markedly different conclusions and policy implications on the importance of grandparent-provided childcare.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the most relevant empirical literature and highlights our main contributions. Section 3 gives a brief history of the Italian pension laws, whose nature assures exogenous variation in grandparental availability for childcare, and describes our empirical strategy. Section 4 describes the data used in our empirical analysis, and Section 5 investigates the relation between pension eligibility and retirement status. Section 6 reports our primary analytical results while the outcomes of several robustness checks are described in an appendix, after which Section 7 reports some back-of-the-envelope calculations of the potential effect of pension laws on maternal aggregate employment. Section 8 summarizes the main findings and concludes the paper.

2 Related literature

The estimation of the causal effect of grandparent-provided childcare on women’s labor supply is fraught with several identification challenges (see Zanella 2017 for a recent review of the literature). One major identification problem is that a simple OLS regression of maternal labor supply on grandparent-provided childcare may lead to biased estimates because this latter is unlikely to be exogenous with respect to the former. At the same time, both the reverse causality of grandparents providing childcare because a woman works and the simultaneous existence of unobservable (or unobserved) characteristics (e.g., grandparental health) that affect female labor supply behavior and informal childcare availability may lead to spurious correlation. One previously attempted solution to this identification issue leverages the arguably exogenous variation in grandparent-provided childcare generated by either the grandparents’ being alive or their retirement eligibility.Footnote 2 For example, Arpino et al. (2014) employ data from the 2003 wave of the ISTAT multipurpose “Family and Social Subjects Survey” (FSSS), which collects information on a mother’s use of grandparental childcare. By instrumenting the latter with grandparents being alive or not, these authors estimate that using grandparent-provided childcare raises a mother’s likelihood of being in the labor market by 32.3 percentage points.Footnote 3 In earlier work, Posadas and Vidal-Fernandez (2013) apply a similar identification strategy to US panel data to demonstrate a positive effect on women’s LFP. Their instrumental variable (IV) estimates, however, are much lower (14.6 percentage points) and less precise (p value = 0.29) than those reported by Arpino et al. (2014) for Italy, partly perhaps because of the two countries’ different institutional settings.Footnote 4

Neither of these studies, however, takes into account that surviving grandparents may greatly differ in the amount of time they can devote to childcare, an aspect acknowledged in two recent papers that exploit differences in grandparental labor market participation generated by changes in retirement eligibility rules. In the first, Aparicio-Fenoll and Vidal-Fernandez (2015; hereafter, AFVF) use age-based pension eligibility as an identification source in three waves (1998, 2003, and 2009) of the FSSS to investigate the effect of grandparental pension eligibility on female fertility and LFP. Using a two-sample, two-stage least squares estimator, they show that the maternal grandmother’s LFP decreases her daughter’s LFP by 21.4 percentage point in the whole sample. Focusing on grandmother’s LFP instead of grandparent-provided childcare implies that their estimate could simultaneously capture alternative mechanisms, namely both grandparent-provided childcare and financial transfers, which may be used by women to buy external childcare. Indeed, the authors explain the surprisingly lower effect (14 percentage point) of grandmother’s LFP for the restricted sample of women with children under 3, whose childcare needs are presumably greater, as an indication of working grandmothers transferring more resources to their daughters. The authors also estimate a reduced form model in which the grandmother’s lack of pension eligibility is directly included in her daughter’s LFP. These estimates, which are comparable with those presented in our paper, produce − 5.1 percentage point and − 3.4 percentage point effects for the whole and restricted samples, respectively. In the other study, which uses only the 2009 wave of the FSSS, Battistin et al. (2015) exploit pension reform-generated exogenous variation to demonstrate a positive effect of grandparental retirement eligibility on female fertility. To explore potential channels for this effect, they also assess the impact of grandparental pension eligibility on employment, reporting estimated effect ranges between 4 and 2.5 percentage points that are concentrated among women under 35 and decrease with a woman’s age.

It is important to highlight certain potential weaknesses in the previous literature using IV estimation. First, instrumental variables require not only that the excluded instruments be exogenous but also that the so-called exclusion restriction assumption hold. The latter implies, for instance, that grandparental deaths should not affect female LFP through channels other than informal childcare provision, conditional on the variables included in the regressions. This assumption may fail in our setting because the monetary transfers that a woman (or her partner) receives from her parents or in-laws—whose effect on her nonlabor income varies her LFP incentives—will likely depend on whether these relatives are alive (dead) or (non)employed. In the case of Posadas and Vidal-Fernandez (2013) and Arpino et al. (2014), for instance, in order for the exclusion restriction to hold, women with deceased parents (in-laws) must have the same nonlabor income availability as those whose parents (in-laws) are still alive. In reality, however, such may not be the case. On the one hand, early loss of a parent (in-law) may entail lower wealth accumulation and lower expected intervivo transfers and inheritances, generating an income or wealth effect on labor supply. On the other hand, if one parent (or in-law) dies, a woman may immediately receive some wealth in the form of inheritance, which could soften household budget constraints, especially when capital markets are imperfect, and the additional resources might partly be used to buy costly external childcare. Thus, the effect of cash and wealth transfers may reinforce or countervail that of grandparent-provided childcare, although in general, it is difficult to assess the bias of the estimates ex-ante when this channel is neglected.

The IV strategy used by AFVF (2015), which estimates the effect of grandmother’s LFP, like we already stressed mixes the effects of childcare and monetary and wealth transfers. Since the authors have no information on such variables, they can only estimate a “gross” effect. In this respect, our data set permits us to include explicit proxies of intervivo transfers and inheritance received by the women and their partners (Section 6.2), allowing us to disentangle the childcare provision channel from other potential effects of grandparental pension eligibility.

Other contributions with respect to the extant literature include the fact that although our identification strategy is similar to that in AFVF (2015), ours uses both age-based retirement pension and contribution-year-based seniority pension rules to define grandparental pension eligibility. At the same time, in contrast to Battistin et al. (2015), our definition of retirement pension eligibility does not assume continuous working lives which, although probably innocuous for grandfathers, could lead to a substantial overestimation of grandmother eligibility given the share of mothers who experience career interruptions or even permanent exit from the labor market around childbearing (Pronzato 2009).Footnote 5 Any such overestimation (or underestimation) of grandparental eligibility (a misclassification error) may lead to an attenuation bias in the estimates (Lewbel 2007). Battistin et al. (2015) also use retrospective data to reconstruct lifecycle labor supply, which, as the authors acknowledge, may be problematic for analyzing labor market behavior because of possible recall errors. By considering only information on mothers’ current employment, we minimize the impact of this recall bias.

A further more substantive difference from both AFVF (2015) and Battistin et al. (2015) is that instead of considering the effect on LFP of all women, we focus only on mothers. Although both effects are of interest, they are potentially different. Our study thus throws light on the potential effect of raising retirement eligibility requirements on the LFP of women who are already mothers via deprivation of grandparental childcare. Previous research, in contrast, estimates the labor supply effect as the average effect on the whole female population, both mothers and nonmothers. This average effect, however, could differ if, for instance, the reforms induced the former to decrease LFP in response to losing grandparental childcare but motivated the latter to postpone or reduce fertility and so increase their labor supply.Footnote 6 The total effect on women’s LFP would then be ambiguously signed. Other important differences are our inclusion of women with deceased grandparents and allowance for differential effects on maternal LFP of the childcare availability of grandparents who never worked versus those who worked and are now pension eligible. As discussed in the next section, we expect these two grandparental caregiver types to have very different effects on female LFP, a theoretical prediction that is indeed supported by the empirical analysis (see Section 7).

3 Using pension reforms to identify the effect of grandparental childcare

3.1 A brief history of pension reforms in Italy

Three major reforms were implemented in Italy during the 1990s to control severe imbalances in the public pension system. Prior to 1992, both retirement requirement and benefit amounts were very generous, with private sector workers allowed to retire at 60 (55 for women) with at least 15 years of contributions (age-based retirement pension) or after 35 years of contributions, independent of age (seniority pension).Footnote 7 The amount of the benefit was based both on contributory years and earnings received during the last working years, with a private sector worker receiving 2% of the average earnings of the last 5 years before retirement for every year of contribution paid. The steep earning profiles of most workers resulted in very generous benefits, leading to a record 1992 benefits/GDP ratio of 16%, which raised the issue of system sustainability and triggered changes in the retirement age and benefits of current and future workers.

In the more general framework of public deficit reduction, the first emergency attempt to balance the pension system budget was the so-called Amato reform (D.Lgs.503/1992), which gradually increased both age and contribution requirements by 5 years. Two years later, the Dini reform (L.724/1994 and L.335/1995) reorganized the system so substantially as to imply a transition from earnings-based to contribution-based benefit computation while decreasing the age requirement but increasing the contribution requirement. It also introduced and regulated a parallel (voluntary) private pension system, which, however, applied only to individuals starting their first job after 1995 or voluntarily opting for the new system.Footnote 8 Finally, the Prodi reform (L.449/1997) modified the part of the Dini reform targeted at older workers, slightly increasing the age requirements and harmonizing the rules for public and private sector employees and self-employed workers.

Table 1 summarizes the minimum age and contribution requirements set by the different reforms for private employees, public employees, and self-employed workers, which we use in the paper to define individual eligibility for a state pension.Footnote 9 As previously explained, workers had some discretion in choosing the requirements-benefits scheme, so for each of the three laws, we report the minimum requirements for every year (half-year for those enacted by July 1) according to gender and employment sector and type. The first column refers to the 1992 Amato reform; the second to the 1995 Dini reform for older workers, as modified by the 1997 Prodi reform; and the third to the 1995 Dini reform for the most recent cohorts of workers. These latter requirements are relevant because older individuals could opt for this system. To illustrate, before the 1992 Amato reform, a 62-year-old male working in the public sector with 30 years of contributions was pension eligible based on both age (60 for public sector workers) and seniority (20 years for public sector workers). In 1993, after the Amato reform, an identical individual was eligible only for a seniority pension because the retirement age had been raised. After 1996, an individual with the same characteristics would have been ineligible based on age (Amato), contribution years (Dini-Prodi), or both (Dini). Hence, consistent with the opportunity to choose the requirement, we assume that workers are eligible for a state pension whenever they satisfy at least one of the three criteria.

Table 1 Eligibility criteria of Italy’s pension reforms

3.2 Empirical strategy

Although we seek to reveal how grandparental childcare determines mothers’ LFP, our data contain no information on whether and how much time grandparents spend with their grandchildren (a variable that would anyway be endogenous to women’s labor market outcomes). Therefore, rather than directly relating women’s employment to grandparental childcare, we correlate the mothers’ LFP with their parents’ and in-laws’ potential availability for childcare by estimating a linear probability model of the following form:

$$ {y}_{it}=\alpha +{\sum}_{k=1}^4\left({\beta}_1^k{NW}_{it}^k+{\beta}_2^k{EL}_{it}^k+{\beta}_3^k{NEL}_{it}^k\right)+{\gamma}^{\prime }{X}_{it}+{\tau}_{rt}+{u}_{it} $$
(1)

where y it is a dummy capturing whether woman i is in the labor force or not in year t. Our main variables of interest are the three dummy variables \( {NW}_{it}^k,{EL}_{it}^k,{NEL}_{it}^k \) which capture the potential availability for childcare of each relative k = 1,… 4, when 1 and 2 are the woman’s mother and mother-in-law, respectively, and 3 and 4, her father and father-in-law. More specifically, \( {NW}_{it}^k \) is equal to 1 if individual k is alive and has never worked (i.e., has always been out of the labor force) and 0 otherwise, and \( {EL}_{it}^k \) \( \left(N{EL}_{it}^k\right) \) is an indicator variable equal to 1 if individual k is alive and (in)eligible for a state pension (based on the pension eligibility rules outlined in the previous subsection). If individual k is not alive, all three variables take the value 0. We also control for all time variant region-specific factors that might affect female employment by including region by year fixed effects (τ rt ), which, among other things, capture differences in the socioeconomic environment (e.g., unemployment) and public childcare provision. Finally, X it is a vector of individual-level variables that may also affect women’s labor supply and employment, including age and education of individual i, and her parents and in-laws, partner’s income and education, and size of the municipality of residence. In the most saturated version of the model, this vector also includes the grandparents’ employment sector (private or public) and type (employee or self-employed).

We exploit two sources of variation to identify the effect of interest: The first is cross-sectional variation determined by differences in the grandparents’ gender, education, and employment sector and type. These latter are generally associated with different ages of entry into the labor market (and thus years of pension contributions conditional on age), as well as different retirement ages even under the same laws (which tend to favor public employees and women). The second is time variation resulting from the pension rule changes introduced by the different reforms passed during our estimation period. In addition to estimating models that exploit each of these two variations, we also compute a more saturated model including all factors determining the grandparental eligibility status, meaning that identification comes only from time variations in the reform-induced eligibility rules. This saturated model enables comparison of like with like; for example, women with parents and in-laws having exactly the same characteristics but whose retirement eligibility status varies because of the law in place at the time. It also controls for grandparent characteristics that, in addition to determining their eligibility status, may also have a direct effect on female employment or be proxies of grandparents’ career orientation (e.g., age, gender, education, and employment sector and type).Footnote 10 It is worth noting that including in the regressions the determinants of the predicted contribution years we are de facto controlling also for the latter, which is a linear combination of the former and thus cannot be included in the regression.

We are primarily interested in the role of grandparents as potential providers of childcare and estimate accordingly Eq. (1) on a sample of women with young children. Our estimation sample includes every woman aged 20–49 who has at least one child under 15 living in the household. As a validity check, we also estimate it for the sample of women in the same age range who have no children under 15 living in the household and for the sample of their male partners. We focus our attention on the coefficients \( {\beta}_1^k,{\beta}_2^k,{\beta}_3^k \), which (multiplied by 100) respectively indicate by how many percentage points a mother is more or less likely to participate in the labor force if her relative k has always been out of the labor force, is eligible for state pension and thus potentially retired from the work force, or is not yet eligible for state pension and thus potentially still employed (or job hunting) relative to the case in which k is dead. Given the predominance of women in childcare provision, we expect to find a positive effect of the availability of maternal and paternal grandmothers for childcare on the women’s LFP probability but a lower (or no) effect of grandfathers’ availability.

Unlike most previous studies, rather than focusing only on the childcare availability of maternal grandmothers, we examine that of all grandparents to avoid any omitted variable bias from its correlating with maternal grandmother availability (e.g., because of similar characteristics like age or education) and affecting women’s LFP. On the other hand, considering the aggregate number of available grandparents could hide heterogeneous effects across grandparents, so for this reason we consider the potential availability for childcare of each grandparent individually. We also include in the estimation sample both women whose parents or in-laws were not alive at the time of interview and those whose parents or in-laws had never participated in the labor market. These two characteristics enable us to not only compute the effect on women’s employment of not having living parents and/or in-laws, but also to test for the presence of heterogeneous effects from parents or in-laws who are available either because they never worked or because they worked in the past and are now retired. These two groups may in fact have very different effects on women’s LFP. We expect that the higher the share of dead grandparents who ever worked, the more \( {\beta}_1^k \) will capture cultural effects in addition to the childcare availability effect. In particular, an intergenerational correlation is possible between a grandmother’s employment and her daughter’s, reflecting either unobservable variables correlated across generations or a true causal relation (e.g., a gender role model).Footnote 11 Conversely, any negative intergenerational correlation between a woman’s LFP and her mother’s never having participated in the labor market may be partly countervailed by the positive effect produced by the latter’s provision of informal childcare. The sign of the net effect is therefore an empirical question. Because it is generally hard to find a convincing exogenous source of variation in parental (especially, maternal) lifetime LFP, rather than attaching a strictly causal interpretation to the estimate of \( {\beta}_1^k \), we consider it only suggestive of potential heterogeneous effects by source of availability. Instead, our main parameter of interest is \( {\beta}_2^k-{\beta}_3^k \), the difference between retirement eligible and ineligible parents or in-laws (who ever worked). These two groups, although very similar in terms of the unobservable variables driving labor force attachment, differ only in their pension rule-induced employment status. We thus interpret this difference causally.

Three other features of our analysis are worth noting. First, unlike those in IV-based studies, our estimation strategy does not require that the grandparent’s retirement eligibility has only an indirect effect on women’s LFP via grandparental childcare. Rather, part of the reduced form (gross) effect estimated of the grandparents’ retirement eligibility on the women’s LFP may be produced by additional causal pathways and not exclusively by grandparental childcare. Therefore, to evaluate the relevance of this latter, we implement several placebo tests; in particular, an estimation of Eq. (1) that assesses whether the effects are larger for individuals with a greater need for childcare than for those who need it less (e.g., women vs. men, women with young children vs. other women). Second, unlike previous researchers, we are able to include control variables that capture certain alternative pathways through which grandparental pension eligibility may affect female LFP, in particular, intervivo transfers and inheritances. Lastly, by focusing on parental and in-law retirement eligibility and not on current retirement status (an endogenous choice variable), we are able to address a potential reverse causality bias; namely, that some grandparents may anticipate their retirement to take care of their grandchildren whose mothers are working (Lumsdaine and Vermeer 2014).Footnote 12

Additionally, note that since not all eligible grandparents actually decide to retire, and not all retired grandparents provide childcare to their children’s family, our paper provides intention-to-treat (ITT) estimates, which must be interpreted as lower bound estimates of the effect of grandparent-provided childcare on maternal employment. In case of effect heterogeneity, IV and ITT estimates provide effects for the individuals affected by the instrument (compliers), namely retirement eligibility. Given the tendency in Italy of individuals to retire as soon as they become eligible (e.g., Brugiavini and Peracchi 2012), the complier population is large enough to be of policy interest.

4 Data

Our analysis is based on data from the SHIW,Footnote 13 administered by the Bank of Italy every 2 yearsFootnote 14 to a rotating panel of 8000 households (approximately 24,000 individuals) per year. In addition to focusing on labor market and income-related issues, the survey also gathers information on such relevant topics as education, sociodemographics, consumption, and dwelling characteristics. Besides providing full information on all household members, household heads and their partners also report the birth year, labor market status, educational attainment, and alive or dead status of their parents,Footnote 15 which we use to analyze grandparental availability for childcare. Because of data availability and comparability, we focus on the seven waves covering 1993–2006, for a total potential population of 55,163 households.

Because the relevant survey unit in the SHIW is the household, for every unit in the sample we use both household-specific (e.g., residential region, household size and composition) and individual-specific (e.g., demographics, education, labor market outcomes, income) variables for all household members. We also exploit the information on the household heads and their partners’ parents. To study the effects of grandparent availability on maternal labor market outcomes, however, we must restrict our sample to a subset of relevant households containing a cohabiting couple who are potential or actual parents. We therefore select all households that include two partners, one a female aged 20–49 for whom we have complete information on both the dependent and independent variables. This selection reduces the sample to 13,443 couples, 8402 (62.5%) of whom are parents to at least one child younger than 15 living in the household, while the remaining 5041 couples (37.5%) either have no offspring or have only children older than 14 or living outside the household.

Table 2 reports the summary statistics for our sample. The women are on average younger than their partners by about 3.5 years, slightly more educated, with a considerably lower LFP rate, about 53% for females versus 98% for males. Interestingly, the female participation rate increases with the age of the children: from 57% for women with no children or children older than 14 in the household to 52% for women with children younger than 6. The grandmothers in the sample are consistently about 4 years younger than the grandfathers, and the maternal grandparents are 4 years younger than both paternal grandparents. The grandmothers, however, are less educated than their partners, and less than 30% of them have ever worked, versus about 93% for grandfathers. The share of grandparents that are not alive also varies substantially, from a minimum of 15% for maternal grandmothers to a maximum of 42% for paternal grandfathers. These differences result from the different birth cohorts: grandfathers are older than grandmothers and men older than women, so that paternal grandfathers are the least likely and maternal grandmothers the most likely to be alive.

Table 2 Sample summary statistics

5 Pension eligibility and retirement

In this paper, we seek to assess the importance of informal childcare provision by grandparents, proxied by their potential availability, on maternal LFP. As described in Section 3, we divide the grandparents’ potential availability into four categories: not alive, never having worked (NW), or in the labor market and either pension eligible (EL) or pension ineligible (NEL). Because the SHIW asks respondents directly about their parents’ labor market participation, age, birth year, and employment sector and type, we have all the information needed to determine pension eligibility, except for years of contribution. To derive this variable, we exploit the fact that the SHIW does record years of pension contributions for all individuals interviewed. First, we regress the actual contribution years on a set of individual characteristics (gender, age, education, employment sector and type, year, and region) available for both the grandparent cohortFootnote 16 and the surveyed individual cohort and then predict the grandparents’ years of contribution on the basis of the estimated coefficients. The regression results are reported in Appendix 1. Once these predictions are obtained, we have all the necessary information to determine whether every grandparent satisfies at least one of the pension requirements and is thus eligible or ineligible for a pension. All regressions using retirement eligibility based on predicted contribution years are bootstrapped (1000 replications) to account for the generated regressors.

We test pension eligibility as a valid predictor of retirement status by running simple regressions of actual individual retirement status of all surveyed individuals (albeit separately for men and women) on both a constant and imputed pension eligibility indicator. The coefficients estimated on this eligibility indicator are 0.719 (SE = 0.006) for men and 0.857 (SE = 0.005) for women,Footnote 17 which, when considered together with our main results (reported below), support the validity of pension eligibility as a predictor of potential childcare availability based on actual retirement.

As already emphasized, rather than relying solely on individual age to define pension eligibility (as in AFVF 2015), we exploit both age-based retirement pension rules and seniority pension rules by combining age with sector of employment, type of activity, and predicted years of contribution. This is a major improvement in identification strategy not only because many of the formerly employed individuals in the grandparent cohort began working at a very young age but because a relevant share of grandparents not meeting the retirement age condition are likely to satisfy the seniority pension criterion of contribution years. In fact, Table 3 does indeed reveal a notable percentage of grandparents eligible based on the contribution requirement while still not meeting the age criterion: 30.5% of fathers, 28.6% of mothers, 33.5% of fathers-in-law, and 33.2% of mothers-in-law. Thus, neglecting the seniority pension criterion would lead to a substantial underestimation of grandparental eligibility, potentially reducing the estimated impact of pension eligibility on female LFP.

Table 3 Eligibility by different criteria

6 Effect of grandparental availability on maternal labor force participation

6.1 Main results

Table 4 reports the results of estimating Eq. (1) for a sample of women aged 20–49 who are either household heads or partners and mothers to at least one child under 15 living in the household. In all cases, the columns reporting the different specifications display the estimated coefficients on the three dummy variables NW, EL, and NEL for the woman’s mother (maternal grandmother), mother-in-law (paternal grandmother), father (maternal grandfather), and father-in-law (paternal grandfather). Column (1) lists the outcomes for the basic specification, which includes only these 12 variables of interest together with region-by-year fixed effects and dummies for municipality size (< 20,000, 20,000–40,000, 40,000–500,000, > 500,000 inhabitants). Column (2) reports the results for an enriched specification that controls for grandparental educational level (up to lower secondary, upper secondary or tertiary, and above), which may proxy for downstream monetary transfers to women, a major channel through which working grandparents may affect women’s LFP. It also controls for grandparents’ age, which in addition to affecting their pension eligibility may also affect their health status and thus a daughter(-in-law)’s LFP. Column (3) adds in a quadratic form for the woman’s age and dummies for her educational level, which may significantly affect her LFP probability. Column (4) then integrates controls for partner’s education and income, both of which may affect female LFP. Our key result is consistent throughout all specifications: having a mother who is eligible for a state pension has a positive and strongly statistically significant effect on the probability of labor force participation for a 20- to 49-year-old woman who is mother to a resident child under 15. The magnitude of the effects implied by the estimates in column (4) is sizable: having a pension-eligible mother implies that her daughter is 10.7 percentage points more likely to participate in the labor force than women whose mother has died, and 8.1 percentage points more likely than those whose mother is currently pension ineligible.Footnote 18

Table 4 Effect of grandparent availability on labor force participation of women with children under 15

The models used in columns (1)–(4) of Table 4 identify the effect of grandparental retirement eligibility by simultaneously exploiting within-year and between-year variation across individuals. Because grandparental eligibility is imputed based on observable characteristics, some of which are excluded from the LFP equation (i.e., employment sector and type), one possible criticism is that these characteristics may also have a direct effect on maternal employment. Hence, in column (5), we add in dummies for public sector employment and self-employment, allowing us to compare the effect on maternal employment of having grandparents with exactly the same observable characteristics but different pension eligibility. Because grandparental pension eligibility as defined in Section 5 is a nonlinear function of these characteristics, even in this saturated model, we still exploit some cross-sectional variation across individuals in grandparental availability. Nevertheless, most identification is achieved through variation in pension eligibility rules over time resulting from the pension reforms described in Section 3. This claim is verified by Fig. 2, which reports the R-squared of year-specific regressions of each grandparent’s pension eligibility status on its determinants. The R-squared is very high in all years, and it increases over time as pension eligibility becomes increasingly linked to years of contribution, from about 0.75 in 1993 to 0.95 in the 2000s. Thus, after 2000, almost all variation in eligibility status comes from pension reforms.

Fig. 2
figure 2

R-squared of year-specific regressions of each grandparent’s eligibility status on its determinants. Note. The figure reports the R-squared of year-specific regressions of dichotomous indicators for each grandparent’s pension eligibility status (eligible or not) on their age, and dummies for educational attainment, public sector employment, self-employment, and region of residence

Even in the saturated model in column (5), the difference between the coefficients on “mother alive and ineligible” and “mother alive and eligible” amounts to 7.1 percentage points (statistically significant at the 5% level), an 11% increase in probability relative to women with ineligible mothers. Moreover, our column (5) estimates show no statistically significant effect of either maternal grandfathers or paternal grandparents on maternal LFP. It is also interesting to note that the coefficients of mother-in-law eligible and mother-in-law ineligible in column (4) are very similar, suggesting a LFP premium that is likely to be related to the mother-in-law’s LFP status rather than to her pension eligibility status, an observation confirmed by the drop in both coefficients in column (5) when grandparental employment characteristics are included. In fact, this latter completely absorbs the effect of paternal grandmothers’ current or past employment status.Footnote 19 It is worth noting that because there might be concerns that some of the grandparents’ characteristics (namely grandparents’ sector and type of job) may be endogenous with respect to mothers’ LFP, the fact that the results are largely insensitive to the exclusion (column 4) of such control variables is quite reassuring.

We report in Appendix 2 the results of a number of additional regressions that we have estimated to check the robustness and sensitivity of our main findings. Specifically, we have replaced the dependent variable with, alternatively, employment status, weekly working hours, hourly wages, annual earnings; used alternative definitions of pension eligibility; and accounted for self-selection into motherhood with a Heckman sample selection model. All these additional checks strengthen the results of our analysis.Footnote 20

6.2 Insights on the causal pathway

Until now, we have shown that women whose mothers are retirement eligible are significantly more likely to participate in the labor market, an effect that does not hold true for the eligibility of their mothers-in-law. We therefore wonder whether grandparental (potential) availability for childcare is a plausible explanation for this finding. If so, we would expect to find evidence that maternal grandparents (grandmothers) are more likely to provide childcare than paternal grandparents (grandmothers). Extant research supports this view: a greater investment in childcare by maternal grandmothers is a very robust pattern in the sociological, psychological, and evolutionary literature (Coall et al. 2014), one recorded for several countries, including the UK, the USA, Australia, Italy, and Norway (see Whelan 2013; Arpino et al. 2014).

We further check the plausibility of the childcare explanation in several interrelated ways. First, we reestimate Eq. (1) for a sample of female household heads or their partners, again in the 20–49 age range, who are not mothers to any cohabiting children under the age of 15. For these women, the potential availability of maternal or paternal grandparents for childcare should have no effect on LFP. We report the results for this alternative sample in column (2) of Table 5 with a focus on the most complete specification (equivalent to that in column (5) of Table 4, whose results we repeat for convenience in column (1) of Table 5). These outcomes offer further support for our interpretation of the effects: for women who have no cohabiting children under 15, there is no indication of a positive effect of the availability of maternal or paternal grandparents on LFP.

Table 5 Effect of grandparental availability on labor force participation by gender and child age

We then perform an even more informative validation test for our proposed explanation by estimating Eq. (1) on the subsample of male partners in the estimation sample. Because men are typically less involved in childcare activitiesFootnote 21 (especially in a Southern European country like Italy), we expect no positive effect of grandparental availability on their LFP unless this availability affects labor market behavior through a channel other than childcare. These results, reported in column (3) of Table 5, indicate that maternal grandparental pension eligibility has no effect on these men’s LFP.

A further test for the plausibility of the childcare channel as the main driver of our results relies on the fact that the childcare burden may be especially high during the child’s earliest years, so it is then that family childcare support may be most important in determining maternal LFP. If the availability of childcare by a grandmother is driving our results, then the younger her daughter’s children, the stronger the effect of the grandmother’s pension eligibility should become. Hence, in the last two columns of Table 5, we restrict our sample to women who have children under the age of 11 (column (4)) and under the age of 6 (column (5)). As expected, the estimated effect of a grandmother’s pension eligibility increases from a baseline of 0.085 for women with children up to 14 to 0.104 and 0.203 for women whose children are under 11 and under 6 (compulsory school entry age), respectively. These estimates imply that women whose children are under 11 and whose mothers are pension eligible are 11% (6.5 percentage points) more likely to participate in the labor force than women whose children are in the same age range but whose mother is not yet pension eligible. The same difference increases to 25% (14.8 percentage points) for women whose children are under 6, a substantially larger effect than the reduced form effect reported in AFVF (2015) in the sample of women with young children.

A distinctive feature of SHIW data, compared to the FSSS data used in a previous work for Italy (see Section 2), is that it provides information on monetary and house transfers received by a woman or her partner from parents and in-laws on monetary transfers from relatives and friends and on home ownership. This provision allows us to sterilize some potential confounders of the effect of grandparent-provided childcare by including additional regressors aimed at capturing potentially concomitant effects of grandparental retirement eligibility in Eq. (1) (e.g., those mediated by wealth effects). Table 6 thus includes monetary transfers and alternative dummy variables for the following: (i) being owner of the dwelling (vs. rent or free use), which controls for a wealth effect; ii) having received the dwelling as a gift, which controls for any additional effect of severance payments received upon retirement in terms of wealth transfer from grandparents; and (iii) having received the dwelling as an inheritance or gift or being able to use it for free, which controls for any additional financial resources that a household may devote to formal or external childcare. Although these control variables may be potential mediating factors (“bad controls,” i.e., potentially affected by grandparent retirement eligibility), this is exactly the reason for their inclusion: to purge out the coefficient on retirement eligibility from the potential mediating factor represented by money and wealth transfers. The three variables are highly correlated, and as shown in columns (1)–(3), the corresponding models exhibit virtually no differences from the baseline model (reported in column (1)). This finding is reassuring evidence of no correlation between retirement eligibility and wealth or monetary transfers, at least as far as these can be measured using the SHIW variables as proxies.

Table 6 Effect of grandparental availability on the labor force participation of women with children under 15 including controls for monetary and wealth transfers

6.3 Heterogeneous effects

We investigate potential heterogeneity in the grandparental eligibility effect based on two factors: women’s educational levels and the potential supply of external childcare. Because less educated women generally command lower wages in the labor market, their LFP and employment decisions are more sensitive to the availability of low-cost, flexible grandparent-provided childcare than those of highly educated women, who may have access to external childcare (Hofferth and Wissoker 1992; Powell 2002). To check this prediction, in column (2) of Table 7, we estimate a saturated model (reported for convenience in column (1)) that additionally includes the interactions between maternal grandmother’s eligibility and the educational attainment of the women in our sample of mothers with cohabiting children. We define as highly educated those women who have completed upper secondary education or more, and as less educated, those who have completed lower secondary education or less.Footnote 22 Less educated women with pension-eligible mothers are 9.7 percentage points more likely to participate in the labor force than their counterparts with ineligible mothers, a difference that is significant at the 10% level. In contrast, the effect for highly educated women, albeit positive, is about 5 percentage points smaller and statistically insignificant.

Table 7 Effect of grandparental availability on the labor force participation of women with children under 15 by educational level and municipal size

Because external childcare could be a substitute for grandparent-provided childcare, we expect the effect of grandparental eligibility to be larger when women have access to fewer childcare alternatives. Since public and private formal childcare is likely to be more abundant in larger municipalities, in column (3) of Table 7, we report the estimates from a model that interacts grandparental eligibility with the size of the municipality of residence. The results are consistent with theoretical expectations. In smaller municipalities (20,000 inhabitants or less), the eligible-ineligible grandmother difference amounts to 11.2 percentage points, while in larger municipalities (over 20,000 inhabitants), the difference is much smaller (2.5 percentage points) and statistically insignificant.Footnote 23 Since geographical mobility of younger individuals is more frequent from smaller to larger municipalities, another possible explanation of this finding is that in the former women are more likely not to have migrated and reside close to their parents or parents-in-law, who could then provide childcare more easily.

7 Discussion

Our finding that women whose mothers are unavailable for childcare suffer a nonnegligible LFP penalty relative to those who can potentially count on such informal assistance throws light on the unintended consequences of pension reforms on maternal labor force participation. In particular, such reforms are likely to penalize women whose mothers become unavailable because of a higher retirement age or stricter retirement requirements. On the other hand, it may also be useful to assess the aggregate effect of pension reforms on the average LFP of all women with children aged 0–14, an effect specific to this demographic group and not to female LFP overall. Overall female LFP may in fact increase if a higher retirement age translates into longer retention of women in the work force. What is likely to change is the distribution of LFP across different generations of women and between women with and without children.

To throw light on this issue, we carry out back-of-the-envelope computations of the average LFP in our sample under different retirement rule scenarios while keeping the sample characteristics fixed. More specifically, we use two scenarios: a pre-Amato scenario and a Dini scenario, in which either the rules predating the Amato reform or the Dini rules (see Table 1) are assumed to be in place for the whole period. After first redefining maternal grandmother eligibility based on these different rule sets, we recompute the average predicted LFP probabilities from our preferred specification for the estimation sample.Footnote 24 The results of this exercise are graphed in Fig. 3. Subfigure (a) shows only a small impact of the retirement rules on average LFP, with year differences ranging between 0.80 (1993) and 0.97 (1998) percentage points (see Appendix 3). These differences correspond to about a 1.7% decline in the labor force participation of mothers. Nevertheless, it must be kept in mind that the main drivers of the average LFP differences between the two scenarios are the differences in share of pension-eligible grandmothers produced by the retirement rules. These latter depend in turn on the demographic characteristics of our estimation sample. For example, high maternal age at first birth is likely to reduce the reform’s impact on female LFP in that most women will then have mothers who are old enough to be retirement eligible no matter what rules we consider in our simulations. Subfigure (b) then reports the aggregate effect (computed in the same way) on mothers of preschool children (0–5), for whom, consistent with the results in Table 4, column (5), the interscenario differences increase. We now observe differences between 2.3 (2000) and 2.9 (1998) percentage points, corresponding to a − 4 and − 5.5% decrease in maternal LFP. Another potential determinant of the pension reforms’ low impact in the sample of all mothers (i.e., with children 0–14) may be that a substantial proportion of maternal grandmothers have never participated in the labor market and so are unaffected by the retirement rule changes. Thus, in subfigure (c), which reports the same two scenarios but with average LFP predicted only for women whose mothers have worked, we observe a much larger gap: the Dini reform has a negative effect on the daughters’ LFP, which peaks in 2000 and amounts to a 4.2% reduction relative to the actual baseline LFP of 67.7%.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Simulated labor force participation rates in the sample of women with children aged 0–14 (a) and 0–5 (b), and whose mother participated in the labor force (c). Note. The figure reports the labor force participation rates of different samples of women computed under different sets of rules on pension eligibility for their mothers. Specifically, the darker line with circles is drawn under the assumption that in all years the eligibility rules are those that were in place until 1992 (i.e., before the Amato reform), whereas the lighter line with squares is drawn under the assumption that in all years the more restrictive rules set by the 1995 Dini reform apply to everyone. The samples consist of all women with children aged 0–14 in subfigure a, all women with children aged 0–5 in subfigure b, and all women with children aged 0–14, whose mothers participated in the labor force in subfigure c

8 Concluding remarks

In Southern European countries such as Italy, which are characterized by very low provision of public childcare, grandparents offer women an important source of informal childcare, which helps them reconcile family and working life. In this paper, therefore, we seek to quantify the effect of such grandparental availability on maternal LFP. We focus on Italy for two reasons: First, its female employment rates are among the lowest in Europe, making it important to identify which factors are hindering the entry of more women into the workforce. Second, the changes in pension eligibility requirements introduced by Italy’s three recent major pension reforms provide exogenous variation in grandparental availability.

Exploiting this exogenous variation, we estimate that mothers of children under 15 whose own mothers are retirement eligible have a 7.1 percentage points higher probability of participating in the labor force (+ 11%) than those whose mothers are ineligible. We interpret this intention-to-treat effect to mean that the potential availability of maternal grandmothers for childcare increases their daughters’ LFP, a conclusion supported by several robustness checks. In fact, we find no such effects for either women with no children under 15 or men, and as could be expected, the magnitude of the effects is larger for women with very young children whose childcare needs are most intensive. These findings remain robust even to controlling for parental downstream transfers, considering female employment instead of LFP and addressing potential selection issues into motherhood. We also show that when fully enforced, the pension reforms imply a 1–1.5% yearly reduction on the LFP rates of women with children aged 0–14 and a 5.5% yearly reduction for those with children aged 0–5. Taken together, these results indicate that pension reforms that raise the retirement age or tighten the requirements for seniority pensions, if not coupled with adequate investments in public childcare, may have unintended negative consequences for the employment probabilities of females of childbearing age by robbing households of an important source of flexible, low-cost childcare.