Skip to main content
Log in

Endogenous fertility and human capital in a Schumpeterian growth model

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study develops a scale-invariant Schumpeterian growth model with endogenous fertility and human capital accumulation. The model features two engines of long-run economic growth: R&D-based innovation and human capital accumulation. One novelty of this study is endogenous fertility, which negatively affects the growth rate of human capital. Given this growth-theoretic framework, we characterize the dynamics of the model and derive comparative statics of the equilibrium growth rates with respect to structural parameters. As for policy implications, we analyze how patent policy affects economic growth through technological progress, human capital accumulation, and endogenous fertility. In summary, we find that strengthening patent protection has (a) a positive effect on technological progress, (b) a negative effect on human capital accumulation through a higher rate of fertility, and (c) an ambiguous overall effect on economic growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Jones (1999) for an excellent review of these subsequent generations of R&D-based growth models.

  2. See, for example, Strulik (2005) for a discussion.

  3. See also Barro and Becker (1989) for a seminal study on endogenous fertility in an overlapping-generation model with exogenous growth.

  4. See also Jones (2003), who analyzes the effects of an exogenous increase in the R&D share of labor chosen by the government. He finds that this policy change increases growth in the short run but decreases growth in the long run through a lower rate of fertility due to a crowding-out effect on labor supply. In contrast, our result of a negative effect of patent breadth on economic growth is based on a higher rate of fertility through an opportunity-cost effect of lower foregone wages.

  5. See Scotchmer (2004) for a comprehensive review of this patent-design literature.

  6. See also Horowitz and Lai (1996).

  7. Early studies on the R&D-based semi-endogenous growth model include Jones (1995), Kortum (1997), and Segerstrom (1998).

  8. Early studies on the second-generation R&D-based endogenous growth model include Young (1998), Dinopoulos and Thompson (1998), and Peretto (1998).

  9. See Laincz and Peretto (2006) and Ha and Howitt (2007) for empirical evidence that supports the second-generation R&D-based growth model.

  10. See Growiec (2006) for an interesting discussion on alternative ways of modeling endogenous fertility in the growth literature.

  11. We follow a common approach in the literature to assume that θ is independent of capital accumulation or technological progress; see also Yip and Zhang (1997) and Connolly and Peretto (2003). Otherwise, as technology or human capital accumulates, θ increases causing a lower time cost of fertility, which in turn leads to a rising fertility rate instead of a constant fertility rate (i.e., ruling out a balanced growth path). However, we think it is reasonable that parental human capital contributes to the health and education of children, and this positive effect is captured by the law of motion for human capital per capita in Eq. 4.

  12. This is known as the Arrow replacement effect in the literature. See Cozzi (2007) for a discussion on the Arrow effect.

  13. We follow the standard approach in the literature to focus on the symmetric equilibrium. See Cozzi et al. (2007) for a theoretical justification for the symmetric equilibrium to be the unique rational-expectation equilibrium in the quality-ladder growth model.

  14. In an earlier version of this study, see Chu and Cozzi (2011), we consider a semi-endogenous-growth version of the model by specifying \(\overline{\varphi }_{t}\) to be decreasing in aggregate technology. In that model, we find that patent breadth has the same effects on fertility as in the current framework. However, the current framework is more general because long-run growth depends also on the R&D share of human capital whereas this R&D share only plays a role on short-run growth, but not on long-run growth in the semi-endogenous growth model.

  15. We assume constant returns to scale at the firm level in order to be consistent with free entry and zero expected profit.

  16. It is useful to recall that a t  = v t /N t .

  17. See Appendix B (available online) for derivations.

  18. See footnote 20 for a discussion.

  19. To see this, differentiating Eq. 23 with respect to ξ yields \(\partial g_{h}/\partial \xi =(1-n/\theta )-(1+\xi /\theta )\partial n/\partial \xi >0\) . Recall that 1 − n/θ > 0 and \(\partial n/\partial \xi <0\).

  20. In the special case of ϕ = 1, it can be shown that patent breadth μ has no effect on the fertility rate n  ∗  leaving only the positive effect on \(s_{r}^{\ast }\).

  21. In an extension of their model with human capital, Futagami and Iwaisako (2007) find that increasing patent length has a negative effect on the wage rate and human capital accumulation via an alternative mechanism other than endogenous fertility.

  22. Jones and Williams (2000) consider a lower bound for ϕ to be about 0.5 based on empirical estimates for the social rate of return to R&D. In this study, we intentionally choose a small value for ϕ in order for TFP growth g z not to be overly responsive to the R&D share of GDP. In our calibration, the elasticity of TFP growth with respect to the R&D share of GDP is about 0.2. If we set ϕ to a higher value of 0.5, the elasticity increases to about 0.5. However, while R&D share of GDP in the USA has been steadily rising, TFP growth shows no significant upward trend.

  23. Persons in households with older children spend even less time for child caring.

  24. We would like to thank a referee for suggesting this interesting extension.

References

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R, Becker G (1989) Fertility choice in a model of economic growth. Econometrica 57:481–501

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessen J, Meurer M (2008) Patent failure: how judges, bureaucrats, and lawyers put innovators at risk. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Boldrin M, Levine D (2008) Against intellectual monopoly. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chu A (2009) Effects of blocking patents on R&D: a quantitative DGE analysis. J Econ Growth 14:55–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chu A, Cozzi G (2011) Cultural preference on fertility and the long-run growth effects of intellectual property rights. MPRA Papers No 29059

  • Chu A, Cozzi G, Galli S (2012) Does intellectual monopoly stimulate or stifle innovation? Eur Econ Rev 56:727–746

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connolly M, Peretto P (2003) Industry and the family: two engines of growth. J Econ Growth 8:115–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cozzi G (2001) Inventing or spying? Implications for growth. J Econ Growth 6:55–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cozzi G (2007) The Arrow effect under competitive R&D. Contrib Macroecon 7:Article 2

  • Cozzi G, Giordani P, Zamparelli L (2007) The refoundation of the symmetric equilibrium in Schumpeterian growth models. J Econ Theory 136:788–797

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cozzi G, Spinesi L (2006) Intellectual appropriability, product differentiation, and growth. Macroecon Dyn 10:39–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cysne R, Turchick D (2012) Intellectual property rights protection and endogenous economic growth revisited. J Econ Dyn Control 36:851–861

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis L, Sener F (2012) Private patent protection in the theory of Schumpeterian growth. Manuscript, Union College

  • Dinopoulos E, Syropoulos C (2007) Rent protection as a barrier to innovation and growth. Econ Theory 32:309–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinopoulos E, Thompson P (1998) Schumpeterian growth without scale effects. J Econ Growth 3:313–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furukawa Y (2007) The protection of intellectual property rights and endogenous growth: is stronger always better? J Econ Dyn Control 31:3644–3670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furukawa Y (2010) Intellectual property protection and innovation: an inverted-U relationship. Econ Lett 109:99–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Futagami K, Iwaisako T (2007) Dynamic analysis of patent policy in an endogenous growth model. J Econ Theory 132:306–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert R, Shapiro C (1990) Optimal patent length and breadth. RAND J Econ 21:106–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1991) Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Rev Econ Stud 58:43–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Growiec J (2006) Fertility choice and semi-endogenous growth: where Becker meets Jones. Top Macroecon 6:Article 10

  • Ha J, Howitt P (2007) Accounting for trends in productivity and R&D: a Schumpeterian critique of semi-endogenous growth theory. J Money Credit Bank 39:733–774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horii R, Iwaisako T (2007) Economic growth with imperfect protection of intellectual property rights. J Econ 90:45–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz A, Lai E (1996) Patent length and the rate of innovation. Int Econ Rev 37:785–801

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iwaisako T, Futagami K (2003) Patent policy in an endogenous growth model. J Econ 78:239–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iwaisako T, Futagami K (2011) Patent protection, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Econ Theory. doi:10.1007/s00199-011-0658-y

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe A, Lerner J (2004) Innovation and its discontents: how our broken system is endangering innovation and progress, and what to do about it. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones C (1995) R&D-based models of economic growth. J Polit Econ 103:759–784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones C (1999) Growth: with or without scale effects. Am Econ Rev 89:139–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones C (2001) Was an industrial revolution inevitable? Economic growth over the very long run. Adv Macroecon 1:Article 1

  • Jones C (2003) Population and ideas: a theory of endogenous growth. In: Aghion P, Frydman R, Stiglitz J, Woodford M (eds) Knowledge, information, and expectations in modern macroeconomics: in honor of Edmund S. Phelps. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones C, Williams J (2000) Too much of a good thing? The economics of investment in R&D. J Econ Growth 5:65–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd K (1985) On the performance of patents. Econometrica 53:567–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kortum S (1992) Inventions, R&D and industry growth. Ph.D. Dissertation, Yale University

  • Kortum S (1997) Research, patenting, and technological change. Econometrica 65:1389–1419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwan Y, Lai E (2003) Intellectual property rights protection and endogenous economic growth. J Econ Dyn Control 27:853–873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laincz C, Peretto P (2006) Scale effects in endogenous growth theory: an error of aggregation not specification. J Econ Growth 11:263–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laitner J, Stolyarov D (2011) Derivative ideas and the value of intangible assets. Manuscript, University of Michigan

  • Li CW (2001) On the policy implications of endogenous technological progress. Econ J 111:C164–C179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus W (1969) Invention, growth, and welfare: a theoretical treatment of technological change. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue T, Zweimuller J (2004) Patents in a model of endogenous growth. J Econ Growth 9:81–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peretto P (1998) Technological change and population growth. J Econ Growth 3:283–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razin A, Ben-Zion U (1975) An intergenerational model of population growth. Am Econ Rev 65:923–933

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98:S71–S102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scotchmer S (2004) Innovation and incentives. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Segerstrom P (1998) Endogenous growth without scale effects. Am Econ Rev 88:1290–1310

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokey N, Rebelo S (1995) Growth effects of flat-rate taxes. J Polit Econ 103:619–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strulik H (2005) The role of human capital and population growth in R&D-based models of economic growth. Rev Int Econ 13:129–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yip C, Zhang J (1997) A simple endogenous growth model with endogenous fertility: indeterminacy and uniqueness. J Popul Econ 10:97–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1998) Growth without scale effects. J Polit Econ 106:41–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Silvia Galli, Oded Galor, and the anonymous referees for their insightful comments and helpful suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Angus C. Chu.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Electronic Supplementary Material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 103 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chu, A.C., Cozzi, G. & Liao, CH. Endogenous fertility and human capital in a Schumpeterian growth model. J Popul Econ 26, 181–202 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-012-0433-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-012-0433-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation