Skip to main content
Log in

Welfare effects of illegal immigration

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes the welfare effect of illegal immigration on the host country within a dynamic general equilibrium framework and shows that it is positive for two reasons. First, immigrants are paid less than their marginal product, and second, after an increase in immigration, domestic households find it optimal to increase their holdings of capital. It is also shown that dynamic inefficiency may arise, despite the fact that the model is of the Ramsey type. Nevertheless, the introduction of a minimum wage, which leads to job competition between domestic unskilled workers and immigrants reverses all of the above results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Of course, there is also an extensive literature that analyzes various aspects of legal immigration within a dynamic growth setting. Recent contributions include Meier and Wenig (1997), Kemnitz and Wigger (2000), and Chen (2006).

  2. Throughout the paper, I am interested in the effects of illegal immigration on the host country. For an analysis of the effects of legal immigration on economic growth of the source country, see Chen (2006).

  3. I am grateful to a referee for calling my attention to the work of Meier and Wenig (1997).

  4. They also analyze the effects on income and wealth of immigrants as well as on the average income and wealth among both natives and immigrants.

  5. Note that the division by N is simply a transformation and it does not mean that immigrants receive dividends. Section 4 below explains the advantage of dividing all variables by N instead of L

  6. As noted in Section 1, Meier and Wenig (1997) analyze legal immigration within a Solow growth model. It is well known that, in the Solow model, the equilibrium capital stock can be on either side of the golden rule path of capital accumulation. Meier and Wenig (1997) show that immigration policy may be used to implement the golden rule. In a similar flavor, in this framework, immigration affects not only the capital stock but also the side relative to the golden rule on which the economy finds itself.

  7. The case where β = 1 corresponds to the case where immigration is legal and immigrants do not save within the country. Hence, if set β = 1 in this section of the paper and the saving rate of the immigrants equal to zero in the Meier and Wenig (1997) paper, then the only difference that remains is that the former uses a Ramsey type and the latter a Solow type growth model. Nevertheless, both papers find the same result.

References

  • Amuedo-Dorantes C, Pozo S (2006) Remittances as insurance: evidence from Mexican immigrants. J Popul Econ 19(2):227–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amuedo-Dorantes C, Bansak C, Pozo S (2005) On the remitting patterns of immigrants: evidence from mexican survey data. Econ Rev Fed Reserve Atlanta 90(1):37–58

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen HJ (2006) International migration and economic growth: a source country perspective. J Popul Econ 19(4):725–748

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein GS, Heizler (Cohen) O (2007) Illegal immigration, enforcement and minimum wage. IZA Discussion Paper, No. 2830

  • Ethier WJ (1986) Illegal immigration. Am Econ Rev 76(2):258–262

    Google Scholar 

  • Hazari BR, Sgro PM (2003) The simple analytics of optimal growth with illegal migrants. J Econ Dyn Control 28(1):141–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemnitz A, Wigger BU (2000) Growth and social security: the role of human capital. Eur J Polit Econ 16(4):673–683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markova E, Reilly B (2007) Bulgarian migrant remittances and legal status: some micro-level evidence from madrid. S-East Eur J Econom 5(1):55–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin P, Miller M (2000) Employer sanctions: French, German and US experiences. International Migration Papers, No. 36

  • Meier V, Wenig A (1997) Welfare implications of international labor migration. Z Wirtsch-Sozialwiss 117(4):505–524

    Google Scholar 

  • Moy HM, Yip CK (2006) The simple analytics of optimal growth with illegal migrants: a clarification. J Econ Dyn Control 30(12):2469–2475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ortega J (2000) Pareto-improving immigration in an economy with equilibrium unemployment. Econ J 110(460):92–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivera-Batiz FL (1999) Undocumented workers in the labor market: an analysis of the earnings of legal and illegal Mexican immigrants in the United States. J Popul Econ 12(1):91–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (2004) World economic and social survey 2004. United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, E/2004/75/Rev.1/Add.1.

  • US Accountability Office (2005) Immigration enforcement: preliminary observations on employment verification and worksite enforcement efforts, June

  • Woodland AD, Yoshida C (2006) Risk preferences, immigration policy and illegal immigration. J Dev Econ 81(2):500–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Hung-Ju Chen, Bharat Hazari, Chong Yip, seminar participants at the Chinese University of Hong Kong, the Kyung Hee University and the University of Cyprus, and especially two anonymous referees for valuable comments and suggestions on an earlier version of the paper. I would also like to thank the Research Committee of the University of Macedonia for financial support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Theodore Palivos.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Appendices

Appendix 1

1.1 The wage rate paid to immigrants

In this Appendix, I offer two alternative justifications for the relative wage rate paid to immigrants, namely, the equation

$$w_{m}=\beta w,\text{ \ \ }\beta \in \lbrack 0,1].$$
(6.1)
  1. (a)

    First, suppose that there is a cost associated with the employment of an undocumented immigrant (a similar approach is followed in Epstein and Heizler 2007). If caught employing an illegal immigrant, which occurs with probability p, an employer must pay a fine γ to the government. Then, maximizing again the representative competitive firm’s profit (Eq. 2.5) with respect to all inputs K, L and M

    $$\Pi =F(K,N)-rK-wL-w_{m}M-p\gamma\! M,$$

    taking all prices as given, yields, besides F K  = r and F L  = w, F M  = w m  + . As F L  = F M , it follows that w − w m  =  > 0; that is, as assumed in the main text, illegal immigrants are paid a wage (w m ) that is lower than the wage rate (w) paid to domestic labor. In particular, as w m  = βw and w − w m  = , it follows that

    $$\beta =\frac{w-p\gamma }{w}.$$
    (6.2)

    Hence, β is determined in equilibrium. Moreover, if either the fine or the probability of being caught is zero, that is, if the expected fine is equal to zero, then the immigrants will be paid as much as the natives. With this formulation, firms will not have any profit, and, thus, there will be no dividend. Hence, we have to examine if the results that are derived in the main text change. Instead of the firms, the revenue from the “exploitation” of the immigrants goes to the government. Indeed, the government raises total revenue equal to

    $$\Pi =p\gamma\! M.$$

    If we assume that this revenue is distributed to domestic households in a lump-sum manner, then

    $$\pi \equiv \frac{\Pi }{N}=p\gamma (1-\alpha ).$$
    (6.3)

    Substituting Eq. 6.3 in the private budget constraint (2.2), we get

    $$\dot{k}=f(k)-\alpha c-(1-\alpha )[w(k)-p\gamma ]-nk.$$
    (6.4)

    The equilibrium path is then determined by Eqs. 2.6 and 6.4. If we make the additional assumption that the fine γ imposed by the government is a multiple of the current wage rate, for example γ = θw, then Eq. 6.4 becomes

    $$\dot{k}=f(k)-\alpha c-(1-\alpha )(1-p\theta )w(k)-nk.$$
    (6.5)

    In this case, the analysis is identical to the one in the main text, as upon setting 1 −  ≡ β, Eqs. 6.5 and 2.8 become identical. Nevertheless, even if one does not accept the simplification γ = θw, all the results still hold. The only difference is that the term w(k) −  replaces now the term βw(k).

  2. (b)

    Suppose instead that the wage rate of the immigrant workers is determined via a bargaining process. Specifically, suppose that, each period, a representative firm bargains with a representative immigrant for the wage rate w m . All negotiations are instantaneous and conducted according to a Nash bargaining rule, in which immigrants receive a share β and firms a share 1 − β in the surplus from a match. If the firm employs an immigrant worker, it gains Π = F(K,N + M) − rK − wL − w m . Instead of the immigrant, the firm can employ a domestic worker, in which case it gains Π  = F(K,N + M) − rK − wL − w. Hence, the gain to a firm employing an illegal immigrant is w − w m . On the other hand, an immigrant can work for the firm and receive w m or return to her country and receive w f . Thus, the gain to an illegal immigrant from accepting to work for a firm in the host country is w m  − w f . The wage rate w m derived from the Nash bargaining solution is such that it maximizes \((w-w_{m})^{1-\beta}(w_{m}-w_{\!f})^{\beta }\), \(\beta \in \lbrack 0,1]\). Performing the suggested differentiation leads to w m  = βw + (1 − β)w f . This equation coincides with Eq. 6.1 if w f  = 0. This can be justified with the additional assumption that the cost for the immigrant of returning to her country is high relative to the benefit. Thus, her outside option is not w f but zero.

Appendix 2

1.1 Immigrants’ saving behavior

In this Appendix, I show that making the alternative assumption, as in Hazari and Sgro (2003) and Moy and Yip (2006), according to which immigrants do not save, instead of sending all their savings abroad, does not change our results. Let us start by specifying the resource constraint in aggregate terms for the economy:

$$\dot{K}+C+C_{M}+S_{M}=F(K,N),$$
(6.6)

where C M and S M denote, respectively, the consumption and savings of the immigrants. Consider the following two alternatives: (a) Immigrants do not save, and hence, their consumption is equal to their income, that is,

$$S_{M}=0\quad \text{and}\quad C_{M}=\beta Mw,$$
(6.7)

or (b) immigrants save but they channel all their savings abroad, that is,

$$S_{M}>0\quad \text{and}\quad C_{M}+S_{M}=\beta Mw.$$
(6.8)

Substituting either of the two Eqs. 6.7 and 6.8 in Eq. 6.6 leads to

$$\dot{K}+C=F(K,N)-\beta Mw,$$

or if we divide both sides by N

$$\dot{k}+ac=f(k)-b(1-\alpha )w-nk,$$

which is the resource constraint (2.8) considered in the main text. Therefore, both alternatives lead to the same resource constraint. Of course, Eq. 2.6, which determines the consumption rule of the natives, also does not change if either assumption is made; thus, the equilibrium remains the same under either assumption. The reason is simply that this is a growth model with full employment. As long as capital accumulation is not affected, whether part of immigrants’ income is spent within the country or abroad does not alter the equilibrium.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Palivos, T. Welfare effects of illegal immigration. J Popul Econ 22, 131–144 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-007-0182-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-007-0182-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation