Skip to main content
Log in

Imperfect goods and labor markets, and the union wage gap

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Existing theoretical literature fails to explain satisfactorily the differences between the pay of workers who are covered by collective agreements and others who are not. This study aims at providing a model framework that is amenable to an analysis of this issue. Our general-equilibrium approach integrates a dual labor market and a two-sector product market. The results suggest that the so-called “union wage gap” is largely determined by the degree of centralization of the bargains and, to a somewhat lesser extent, by the expenditure share of the unionized sector's goods.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Blanchflower and Bryson (2003) use more recent data and adjust for bias due to earnings imputations (see Hirsch and Schumacher 2004). Their results suggest that the union wage gap has declined from 22.4% in 1984 to 15.1% in 2001 (private sector).

  2. For a more general formulation, see Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003, p. 881).

  3. If workers were distributed unevenly, some of them could increase the probability of an employment by reallocating themselves to a firm where less workers are attached.

  4. Since all agents fare better in the case of an agreement, this second term serves only as the “conflict point” during the bargain, but is never realized.

  5. As noted earlier, wages, demand, labor input, and so forth are the same for all firms in a symmetric equilibrium. Nevertheless, the bargaining parties consider these variables to depend on the result of the bargain if they are related to them, and as exogenous if they are related to other firms/workers.

  6. Unfortunately, the definition and measurement of bargaining coverage are not unambiguous. One difference between the reported coverage rates is that some of them adjust for the fact that, in several countries, not all workers have the legal right to bargain. From the role of the parameter in the model, it is clear that we must take the unadjusted coverage rate. Therefore, the OECD data were only viable for those countries where all workers have the right to bargain, so that both rates coincide. For instance, this is the case in Italy.

  7. The 1994 value has to be taken from 1993, which is the last one published.

  8. To avoid computational problems, a value of 0.0001 rather than literally zero is the minimum (employed for USA and Canada).

  9. This source converts the national data such that they approximate US concepts. The Danish values stem from OECD (2001, p. 20f).

  10. These values are comparable with those of Elbehri and Hertel (1999).

  11. I would like to thank one anonymous referee for making this point.

References

  • Antweiler W, Trefler D (2002) Increasing returns and all that: a view from trade. Am Econ Rev 92(1):93–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M, Kramarz F (2002) Does entry regulation hinder job creation? evidence from the French retail industry. Q J Econ 117(4):1369–1413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Giavazzi F (2003) Macroeconomic effects of regulation and deregulation in goods and labor markets. Q J Econ 118(3):879–908

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower DG (1996) The role and influence of trade unions in the OECD. Discussion Paper 310. Centre for Economic Performance, London, UK

  • Blanchflower DG (1999) Changes over time in union relative wage effects in Great Britain and the United States. In: Daniel S, Arestis P, Grahl J (eds) The history and practice of economics: essays in honour of Bernard Corry and Maurice Peston. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 3–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower DG, Bryson A (2003) Changes over time in union relative wage effects in the UK and the US revisited. Working Paper 9395. NBER, Cambridge, MA

  • Blanchflower DG, Bryson A (2004) What effects do unions have on wages now and would ‘what do unions do?’ be surprised? J Labor Res 25(3):383–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower DG, Freeman RB (1992) Unionism in the US and other advanced OECD countries. In: Bognanno M, Kleiner M (eds) Labor market institutions and the future role of unions. Blackwell, Oxford, pp 56–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Boeri T, Nicoletti G, Scarpetta S (2000) Regulation and labour market performance. In: Galli G, Pelkmans J (eds) Regulatory reform and competitiveness in Europe. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 324–380

    Google Scholar 

  • Boeri T, Brugiavini A, Calmfors L (eds) (2001) The role of unions in the twenty-first century. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Booth AL, Bryan ML (2004) The union membership wage–premium puzzle: is there a free rider problem? Ind Labor Relat Rev 57(3):402–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bratsberg B, Ragan JF (2002) Changes in the union wage premium by industry—data and analysis. Ind Labor Relat Rev 56(1):65–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calmfors L, Driffill EJ (1988) Bargaining structure, corporatism and macroeconomic performance. Econ Policy 3(1):13–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elbehri A, Hertel TW (1999) Economic integration, market structure and growth dynamics. Paper presented at the Second Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis, Denmark

  • Freeman RB, Medoff JL (1984) What do unions do? Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch BT (2004) Reconsidering union wage effects: surveying new evidence on an old topic. J Labor Res 25(2):233–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch BT, Schumacher EJ (2004) Match bias in wage gap estimates due to earnings imputation. J Labor Econ 22(3):689–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iversen T (1998) Wage bargaining, central bank independence, and the real effects of money. Int Organ 52(3):469–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jean S, Nicoletti G (2002) Product market regulation and wage premia in Europe and North America: an empirical investigation. Working Paper 318. OECD Economics Department, Paris, France

  • Kenworthy L (2003) Quantitative indicators of corporatism. Int J Sociol 33(3):10–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell SJ (1999) Product markets and labour markets. Labour Econ 6(1):1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicoletti G, Bassanini A, Ernst E, Jean S, Santiago P, Swaim P (2001) Product and labour markets interactions in OECD countries. Working Paper 312. OECD Economics Department, Paris, France

  • OECD (1997) OECD employment outlook. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2001) Labor force statistics: 1980–2000. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Oliveira Martins J, Scarpetta S, Pilat D (1996) Mark-up rations in manufacturing industries: estimates for 14 OECD countries. Working Paper 162. OECD Economics Department, Paris, France

  • Robinson C (1989) The joint determination of union status and union wage effects: some tests of alternative models. J Polit Econ 97(3):639–667

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roeger W (1995) Can imperfect competition explain the difference between primal and dual productivity measures? Estimates for US manufacturing. J Polit Econ 103(2):316–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Paul G (1996) Dual labor markets: a macroeconomic perspective. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Soskice D (1990) Wage determination: the changing role of institutions in advanced industrialized countries. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 6(4):36–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Traxler F (1996) Collective bargaining and industrial change: a case of disorganization? A comparative analysis of eighteen OECD countries. Eur Sociol Rev 12(3):271–287

    Google Scholar 

  • US Department of Labor (2002) Comparative civilian labor force statistics: ten countries, 1959–2001. http://www.bls.gov/fls/flsforc.pdf

  • Visser J (2003) Unions and unionism around the world. In: Addison JT, Schnabel C (eds) The international handbook of trade unions. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 366–413

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The first draft of this paper has been prepared during a visit to the Universitá degli Studi di Modena e Reggio Emilia. I thank the entire Economics Department (in particular Graziella Bertocchi, Marina Murat, and Sergio Paba) for the hospitality I received. I would also like to thank Christian Dustmann, Chiara Strozzi, and two anonymous referees for their comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Helge Sanner.

Additional information

Communicated by Christian Dustmann.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sanner, H. Imperfect goods and labor markets, and the union wage gap. J Popul Econ 19, 119–136 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0010-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0010-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation