Skip to main content
Log in

Schumpeter's early work

  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

The social process is really one indivisible whole. Out of its great stream the classifying hand of the investigator artificially extracts economic facts. Joseph A. Schumpeter Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (1911)

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

References

  1. This article draws heavily on chapter 2 in the author'sSchumpeter—A Biography (Princeton University Press, Princeton, 1991).

  2. Arthur Spiethoff, “Josef Schumpeter in Memoriam”,Kyklos 3 (1950), p. 291. The quote at the beginning of this article comes fromTheorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (1911) as translated in 1934 asThe Theory of Economic Development (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1934), p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See e.g. Joseph A. Schumpeter,Ten Great Economists (Oxford University Press, New York, 1951), p. 87.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Léon Walras,Correspondance of Léon Walras and Related Papers, edited by William Jaffe North-Holland Publishing Company, Amsterdam, 1965), vol. III, p. 385.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Erich Schneider, ‘Schumpeter's Early German Works, 1906–1917’, inSchumpeter, Social Scientist, ed. Seymour Edwin Harris (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 1951), pp. 54–58.

    Google Scholar 

  6. —Ibid., p. 54.

    Google Scholar 

  7. See e.g. Richard Swedberg, ‘Joseph A. Schumpeter and the Tradition of Economic Sociology’,Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics,145 (1989), pp. 510–511.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Schumpeter's vita in Akt Nr. 9501 vom 8. März 1909 des k.k. Ministeriums für Kultus und Unterricht, Dep. Nr. VII, Allgemeines Verwaltungsarchiv, Vienna. Schumpeter also refers to this experience in a footnote inBusiness Cycles. See Joseph A.Schumpeter,Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process (McGraw-Hill Books Co., New York, 1939), vol. I, p. 223.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Joseph A. Schumpeter, ‘Über die internationale Preisbildung (Auszug)’,Statistische Monatsschrift, 10 (1905), pp. 923–928.

    Google Scholar 

  10. —Ibid., p. 923.

    Google Scholar 

  11. —Ibid., p. 925.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Schumpeter's contribution toStammbuch (II) der Philosophischen Fakultät der Universität Bonn of the Archives of the University of Bonn.

  13. Schumpeter to Lloyd S. Huntsman, May 26, 1941 (Harvard University Archives=HUA).

  14. Joseph A.Schumpeter,Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen Nationalökonomie (Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig, 1908), p. 20.

    Google Scholar 

  15. —Ibid.,Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen Nationalökonomie (Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig, 1908, p. xxi.

    Google Scholar 

  16. —Ibid.,Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen Nationalökonomie (Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig, 1908, p. xiv.

    Google Scholar 

  17. —Ibid.,Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen Nationalökonomie (Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig, 1908, p. vii. Emphasis added.

    Google Scholar 

  18. —Ibid., pp. 91, 575. Later in life Schumpeter would reevaluate his position and have a more positive opinion of the role of ideology in economics. Ideology would still be seen as detrimental to economics—but without a Vision (which inevitably includes ideology), there would be no progress in economic theory, Schumpeter now adds.

    Google Scholar 

  19. —Ibid., p. 90. Emphasis in the text has been removed.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Max Weber, “‘Objectivity’ in Social Science and Social Policy”, inThe Methodology of the Social Sciences, tr. E. A. Shils and H. A. Finch (The Free Press, New York, 1949), pp. 49–112.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Schumpeter,Das Wesen,—, p.45.

    Google Scholar 

  22. —Ibid., p. 536. Emphasis added.

    Google Scholar 

  23. —Ibid., p. 540.

    Google Scholar 

  24. —Ibid., p. 553.

    Google Scholar 

  25. —Ibid., p. 536.

    Google Scholar 

  26. —Ibid., p. 28.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Schumpeter uses the term “Beschreibung” for theoretical economics. For the kind of description that historians engage in, he reserves the term “Deskription”. See e.g.—ibid., p. 289, 37, 42.

    Google Scholar 

  28. —Ibid., p. 43.

    Google Scholar 

  29. —Ibid., p. 44.

    Google Scholar 

  30. —Ibid., p. 94.

    Google Scholar 

  31. —Ibid., p. 573. I thank Murray Milgate for telling me about the intellectual history of the “sea level” and “equilibrium” analogy. According to Milgate, Walras got it from Turgot; and it actually goes back to at least some of the English mercantilists.

    Google Scholar 

  32. I owe this important point to Prof. Yuichi Shionoya.

  33. Das Wesen—, p. 184, 567.

    Google Scholar 

  34. —Ibid., p. 182–183.

    Google Scholar 

  35. —Ibid., p. 626.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Schumpeter in a letter to Edwin R. Seligman in 1913 as cited in Robert Loring Allen,Opening Doors: The Life and Work of Joseph Schumpeter (Transaction Press, New Brunswick, 1991), vol. 1, p. 132.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Friedrich von Wieser, ‘Review of Schumpeter,Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen Nationalökonomie’,Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft, 35 (1911), pp. 395–417; and Léon Walras to Georges Renard, December 24, 1908 —Correspondance of Léon Walras, p. 384.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Othamar Spann, ‘Die mechanisch-mathematische Analogie in der Volkswirtschaftslehre’,Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, 30 (1910), pp. 786–824.

    Google Scholar 

  39. ‘Professor Schumpeter, Austrian Minister, Now teaching Economic Theory Here’,The Harvard Crimson, April 11, 1944. See also Schumpeter to Taksyasu Kimura and Takumam Yasui, August 12, 1936 (HUA).

  40. Von Wieser, ‘Review of Schumpeter’—, p. 417.

    Google Scholar 

  41. See e. g. Schumpeter,Das Wesen—, p. 94, 198.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Schumpeter to Léon Walras, October 9, 1908 —Correspondance of Léon Walras, p. 378.

  43. Joseph A. Schumpeter,Essays (Transaction Press, New Brunswick, 1989), p. 166. Schumpeter describes how he changed his opinion of Walras in his preface to the Japanese translation ofTheorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, which is signed June 1937.

    Google Scholar 

  44. —Ibid

    Google Scholar 

  45. —Ibid. Emphasis added.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Joseph A. Schumpeter,Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig, 1912), p. x.

    Google Scholar 

  47. 47.—Ibid., p. xi.

    Google Scholar 

  48. —Ibid., p. 487.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Joseph A. Schumpeter,The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle (translated by R. Opie; Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 1934) pp. 21–22. I shall often cite this English edition when discussing Schumpeter's 1911 book, since it represents the best-known version. The english translation is based on the second edition ofTheorie, which appeared in 1926. According to Schumpeter's preface to the second edition, “the argument itself has nowhere been altered” (even if there exist some other changes between the two editions) — see Schumpeter,Theory, p. xii. The two books, however, are often different; and it is, for example, often pointed out that the concept of innovation is missing from the 1911 version. But even if this is true, theidea of innovation is clearly present in the 1911 version. Schumpeter thus defines entrepreneurship in terms of putting together new ‘combinations”, and he distinguishes very clearly between entrepreneurs and inventors. See Schumpeter,Theorie (1912), pp. 158–159, 178–179.

    Google Scholar 

  50. —, p. 64.

    Google Scholar 

  51. —Ibid., p. 74.

    Google Scholar 

  52. —, p. 68.

    Google Scholar 

  53. —, p. 66.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Schumpeter,Theorie—, p. 529.

    Google Scholar 

  55. —Ibid. pp. 21–22.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Schumpeter,Theory— (Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig, 1912) p.65.

    Google Scholar 

  57. This quote, as well as the one in the preceeding line, come from—ibid. p. 82.

    Google Scholar 

  58. For a comparison between Schumpeter and Weber on this point see especially Edward Carlin, ‘Schumpeter's Constructed Type’,Kyklos, 9 (1956), pp. 27–42.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Schumpeter,Theory—, p. 93.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Here, as elsewhere in the text, I have decided to not present an overly detailed (and thereby technically correct) picture of Schumpeter's economic theory. Credit and capital are, for example, not identical in Schumpeter's scheme. For exact definitions, see—ibid. pp. 116–117.

    Google Scholar 

  61. —Ibid. p. 212.

    Google Scholar 

  62. —Ibid. p. 224.

    Google Scholar 

  63. Joseph A. Schumpeter,Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung: Eine Untersuchung über Unternehmergewinn, Kapital, Kredit, Zins und den Konjunkturzyklus, 2nd edn (Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig, 1926), p. xiii.

    Google Scholar 

  64. Schumpeter,Theorie—, p. 464.

    Google Scholar 

  65. —Ibid. p. 518.

    Google Scholar 

  66. —Ibid. p. 56.

    Google Scholar 

  67. —Ibid. p. 526.

    Google Scholar 

  68. —Ibid. p. 535.

    Google Scholar 

  69. —Ibid. p. 535.

    Google Scholar 

  70. —Ibid. p. 538.

    Google Scholar 

  71. —Ibid. p. 546–547.

    Google Scholar 

  72. —Ibid. p. 548.

    Google Scholar 

  73. Schumpeter to David T. Pottinger, June 4, 1934 (HUA).

  74. Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, “Eine ‘dynamische’ Theorie des Kapitalzinses”, inEugen von Böhm-Bawerks kleinere Abhandlungen über Kapital und Zins, ed. Franz X. Weiss (Holder-Pichler-Tempsky A.G., Vienna, 1926), vol. II, p. 585.

    Google Scholar 

  75. Joseph A. Schumpeter, “Eine ‘dynamische’ Theorie des Kapitalzinses: Eine Entgegnung”, inAufsätze zur ökonomischen Theorie (J.C.B. Mohr, Tübingen, 1952), pp. 411–412.

    Google Scholar 

  76. Schumpeter to Pottinger.

  77. See the bibliography by Massimo M. Augello on pp. 445–481 in Joseph A. Schumpeter, edited with an introduction by Richard Swedberg,The Economics and Sociology of Capitalism (Princeton University Press, New Jersey, 1991).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Swedberg, R. Schumpeter's early work. J Evol Econ 2, 65–82 (1992). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01196461

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01196461

Keywords

Navigation