Advertisement

Communication Cost, Skilled-Unskilled Wage, and Informality

  • Biswajit Mandal
  • Sujata GhoshEmail author
Original Article
  • 7 Downloads

Abstract

This paper establishes an interesting link between informality and time zone differences in a general equilibrium trade model for small open economy. Trading countries are located in different time zones of the world with non-overlapping working hours. Such differences in timing can be utilized in the production of services, and communication technology is an important factor that helps this trading process. In such a setup due to a reduction in communication cost, both skilled and unskilled workers are benefitted, skilled labour using service sector and formal unskilled sector expand. Interestingly, wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers is widened under reasonable conditions. Another phenomenon that must draw our attention is the contraction of informality due to such changes. Then we extend the basic model to include capital mobility across all sectors and unionized wage in the formal sector. We find that the reduction in communication cost leads to finite change in the structure of production and one of the four sectors of the system vanishes. Subsequently, informal sector contracts while wage disparity is widened.

Keywords

International trade General equilibrium Time zone differences Informal sector 

JEL Classification

F 1 D 58 F 2 F 11 

Notes

References

  1. Anderson, E. 2014. Time Differences, communication and trade: Longitude matters II. Review of World Economics 150 (2): 337–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Christen, E. 2012. Time zones matter: The impact of distance and time zones on services trade. The World Economy 40 (3): 612–631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Dettmer, B. 2014. International service transactions: Is time a trade barrier in a connected world ? International Economic Journal 28 (2): 225–254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Dixit, A.K., and G.M. Grossman. 1982. Trade and Protection with Multistage Production. Review of Economic Studies 49: 583–594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Dutta, M., S. Kar, and S. Marjit. 2013. Product variety, finite changes and wage inequality. CSSSC: Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Findlay, R., and R.W. Jones. 2000. Factor Bias and Technical Progress. Economic Letters 68: 303–308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Jones, R.W. 1965. The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models. Journal of Political Economy 73 (6): 557–572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Jones, R.W. 1971. A three-factor model in theory, trade and history. In Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth, ed. J. Bhagwati, 3–21. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  9. Jones, R.W. 1974. The Small Country in a Many-Commodity World Duality in International Trade : A Geometrical Note. Australian Economic Papers 13: 225–236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Jones, R.W., and S. Marjit. 1992. International Trade Theory and Endogenous Production Structures. In Economic Theory and International Trade-Essays in Honor of T. Rader, ed. W. Neuefeind and R. Riezman. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
  11. Kikuchi, T. 2006. Time Zones, Outsourcing and Patterns of International Trade. Economics Bulletin 6 (15): 1–10.Google Scholar
  12. Kikuchi, T. 2008. Distribution Costs, International Trade and Industrial Locations. Economics Bulletin 6 (24): 1–5.Google Scholar
  13. Kikuchi, T. 2009. Time Zones as a Source of Comparative Advantage. Review of International Economics 17 (5): 961–968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Kikuchi, T. 2011. Time Zones, Communication Networks, and International Trade. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Kikuchi, T., and S. Marjit. 2011. Growth with Time Zone differences. Economic Modelling 28 (1): 637–640.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Kikuchi, T., S. Marjit, and B. Mandal. 2013. Trade with Time Zone differences: Factor Market Implications. Review of Development Economics 17 (4): 699–711.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Melitz, J. 2007. North, South and Distance in the Gravity Model. European Economic Review 51 (4): 971–991.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Mandal, B. 2015. Distance, Production, Virtual Trade and Growth. Economics The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 9 (2015–1): 1–12.Google Scholar
  19. Mandal, B., S. Marjit, and N. Nakanishi. 2018. Outsourcing, Factor Prices and Skill Formation in Countries with Non-overlapping Time Zones. Eurasian Economic Review 8 (2): 289–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Marjit, S. 1987. Trade in Intermediates and the Colonial Pattern of Trade. Economica 54: 173–184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Marjit, S. 2003. Economic Reform and Informal Wage- A general Equilibrium Analysis. Journal of Development Economics 72: 371–378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Marjit, S. 2007. Trade Theory and the Role of Time Zones. International Review of Economics and Finance 16: 153–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Marjit, S., S. Kar (2011), “International Capital Flow, Finite Change and Two-sided Wage Inequality”, mimeo, CSSSC.Google Scholar
  24. Matsuoka, Y., and M. Fukushima. 2010. Time Zones, Shift Working and International Outsourcing. International Review of Economics and Finance 19: 769–778.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Prasad, A., B. Mandal, and P. Bhattacharjee. 2017. Time Zone Difference, Comparative Advantage and Trade: A Review of Literature. Eurasian Journal of Economics and Finance 5 (3): 1–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Sanyal, K. 1983. Vertical Specialization in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Stages of Production. Economica 50 (197): 71–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Sanyal, K., and R.W. Jones. 1982. The Theory of Trade in Middle Products. American Economic Review 72 (1): 16–31.Google Scholar
  28. Strategic Review. 2015. The IT-BPM Sector in India: Strategic Review.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Indian Econometric Society 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Economics and PoliticsVisva-Bharati UniversitySantiniketanIndia

Personalised recommendations