Advertisement

Triggering cooperation among firms: an empirical assessment of the Italian Network Contract Law

  • Riccardo Leoncini
  • Giulia Vecchiato
  • Luca Zamparini
Original Paper
  • 20 Downloads

Abstract

In this paper, we empirically investigate if and how the Italian Law on Network Contracts was able to trigger the establishment of networks among the involved firms. This law defined network contracts as agreements among firms to cooperate in order to improve, both individually and collectively, their innovative capacity and competitiveness in the market. It promoted them in virtually all Italian regions. During the year 2012, 213 network contracts were signed involving a total of 1083 firms. The empirical analysis shows that network contracts provide an answer to the various needs that the firms involved, if acting as single entities, cannot tackle. Indeed, on the one side, when firms that signed a network contract were characterised by mixed types of ownerships regimes, this fact negatively affected the performance of the firms involved although they ranked in the top positions in terms of correspondence with the aims of the law. The opposite holds when we consider firms within network contracts characterised by the presence of joint shareholding: this shows that despite a positive impact on performance, these networks are not specifically targeted by the law.

Keywords

Contract law Italy Theory of the firm 

JEL Classification

D2 K12 L14 

Notes

References

  1. Akçomaka, S., & ter Weel, B. (2009). Social capital, innovation and growth: evidence from Europe. European Economic Review, 53, 544–567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Antonietti, R., Ferrante, M. R., & Leoncini, R. (2014). Spatial agglomeration, production technology and the choice to make and/or buy: empirical evidence from the Emilia Romagna machine tool industry. Regional Studies, 48(2), 284–300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Baker, G., Gibbons, R., & Murphy, K. J. (2002). Relational contracts and the theory of the firm. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 39–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Baker, G. P., Gibbons, R., & Murphy, K. J. (2008). Strategic alliances: bridges between “islands of conscious power”. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 22(2), 146–163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Becattini, G. (2002), From Marshall to the Italian Industrial Districts. A Brief Critical Reconstruction, in Complexity and Industrial Clusters, Springer, New York.Google Scholar
  6. Behzadian, M., Kazemzadeh, R., Albadvi, A., & Aghdasi, M. (2010). Promethee: a comprehensive literature review on methodologies and applications. European Journal of Operational Research , 200, 198–215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Brandenburger, A. M., & Nalebuff, B. J. (1996). Coopetition. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
  8. Brusco, S. (1982). The Emilian model: productive decentralisation and social integration. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 6(2), 167–184.Google Scholar
  9. Bürker, M., & Minerva, G. A. (2014). Civic capital and the size distribution of plants: short-run dynamics and long-run equilibrium. Journal of Economic Geography, 14, 797–847.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Cainelli, G., & Leoncini, R. (1999). Externalities and long-term industrial development: some empirical evidence from Italy. Revue d’Economie Industrielle, 90, 25–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cantner, U., Conti, E., & Meder, A. (2010). Networks and innovation: the role of social assets in explaining firms’ innovative capacity. European Planning Studies , 18(12), 1937–1956.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Cartocci, R. (2007). Mappe del tesoro. Atlante del capitale sociale in Italia. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
  13. Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in innovation strategy: internal R&D and external knowledge acquisition. Management Science , 52, 68–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Christensen, L., Jorgenson, D., & Lau, L. (1971). Conjugate duality and the transcendental logarithmic production function. Econometrica, 39(4), 255–256.Google Scholar
  15. Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Coase, R. H. (1992). The institutional structure of production. American Economic Review, 82(4), 713–719.Google Scholar
  17. Cobb, C., & Douglas, P. (1928). A theory of production. American Economic Review, 18(1), 139–165.Google Scholar
  18. Crepon, B., Duguet, E., & Mairesse, J. (1998). Research, innovation and productivity. An econometric analysis at the firm level. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 7, 115–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. de Blasio, G., & Nuzzo, G. (2009). Historical traditions of civicness and local economic development. Journal of Regional Science, 50, 833–857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Dodgson, J., Spackman, M., Pearman, A., & Phillips, L. (2009). Multi-Criteria Analysis. A Manual. London: Department for Communities and Local Government.Google Scholar
  21. Eigenhüller, L., Litzel, N., & Fuchs, S. (2015). Who with whom: co-operation activities in a cluster region. Papers in Regional Science, 94, 469–497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Gamper, C. D., & Turcanu, C. (2007). On the governmental use of multi-criteria analysis. Ecological Economics, 62(2), 298–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Glaeser, E., Kallal, H., Scheinkman, J., & Shleifer, A. (1992). Growth in cities. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 1126–1152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Grandori, A., & Soda, G. (1995). Inter-firm networks: antecedents, mechanisms and forms. Organization studies, 16(2), 183–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Henderson, V., Kunkoro, A., & Turner, M. (1995). Industrial development in cities. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 1067–1090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Huggins, R., & Johnston, A. (2010). Knowledge flow and inter-firm networks: the influence of network resources, spatial proximity and firm size. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 22(5), 457–484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Inkpen, A. C., & Tsang, E. W. K. (2005). Social capital, networks, and knowledge transfer. Academy of Management Review, 30, 146–165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Jolink, A., & Niesten, E. (2012). Recent qualitative advances on hybrid organizations: taking stock, looking ahead. Scandinavian Journal of Management, 28(2), 149–161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1251–1288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Kumbhakar, S., & Lovell, C. (2000). Stochastic Frontier Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Laursen, K., Masciarelli, F., & Prencipe, A. (2012). Regions matter: how localized social capital affects innovation and external knowledge acquisition. Organization Science, 23(1), 177–193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Lechner, C., & Dowling, M. (2003). Firm networks: external relationships as sources for the growth and competitiveness of entrepreneurial firms. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 15(1), 1–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Lechner, C., & Leyronas, C. (2012). The competitive advantage of cluster firms: the priority of regional network position over extra-regional networks. A study of a French high-tech cluster. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 24(5–6), 457–473.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of Economics, 8th ed. London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
  36. Mauro, L. & F. Pigliaru (2011), Social Capital, Institutions and Growth: Further Lessons from the Italian Regional Divide, WP Crenos, 2011/03.Google Scholar
  37. Menard, C. (2004). The economics of hybrid organizations. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 160, 345–376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Menard, C. (2011). Is Public-Private Partnership Obsolete? Assessing the Obstacles and Shortcomings of PPP. In P. De Vries & E. Yehoue (Eds.), The Routledge Companion to Public-Private Partnership. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  39. Menard C. (2012). Hybrid Modes of Organization. Alliances, Joint Ventures, Networks, and Other ‘Strange’ Animals, in R. Gibbons and J. Roberts (eds.), The Handbook of Organizational Economics, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1066–1108.Google Scholar
  40. Ménard, C. (2006). Hybrid organization of production and distribution. Revista de Análisis Económico, 21(2), 25–41.Google Scholar
  41. Moretti, A. (2017). The Network Organization. A Governance Perspective on Structure, Dynamics and Performance. Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
  42. Niesten, E., & Jolink, A. (2015). The impact of alliance management capabilities on alliance attributes and performance: a literature review. International Journal of Management Reviews, 17(1), 69–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Nunes, S., & Lopes, R. (2015). Firm performance, innovation modes and territorial embeddedness. European Planning Studies, 23(9), 1796–1826.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Parmigiani, A. (2007). Why do firms both make and buy? An investigation of concurrent sourcing. Strategic Management Journal, 28, 285–311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Parmigiani, A., & Mitchell, W. (2009). Complementarity, capabilities, and the boundaries of the firm: the impact of within-firm and inter-firm expertise on concurrent sourcing of complementary components. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 1065–1091.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Penrose, E. T. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. USA: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  47. Putnam, R. D., R. Leonardi, and R. Y. Nanetti (1993), Making Democracy Work. Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  48. Richardson, G. B. (1972). The organisation of industry. Economic Journal, 82(327), 883–896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Thorelli, H. B. (1986). Networks: between markets and hierarchies. Strategic Management Journal, 7(1), 37–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Williamson, O. E. (1991). Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly , 2(36), 269–296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Zak, P. J., & Knack, S. (2001). Trust and growth. Economic Journal, 111, 295–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Zamparini, L., & Reggiani, A. (2010). Evaluation of infrastructure investments: the case of the Southern Italian transport network. Scienze Regionali, 9(Suppl. n. 3), 43–74.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Freiburg Institute for Advanced Studies (FRIAS)University of FreiburgFreiburg Im BreisgauGermany
  2. 2.Department of LawUniversity of BolognaBolognaItaly
  3. 3.IRCrES-CNRMilanItaly
  4. 4.Studio Legale Daldosso VecchiatoMilanItaly
  5. 5.Department of LawUniversity of SalentoLecceItaly

Personalised recommendations