History friendly models: retrospective and future perspectives
Regular Article
First Online:
Abstract
Twenty years ago, we introduced the history friendly modeling approach to formally study industrial dynamics. In this paper, we look retrospectively at the results that the history friendly literature has achieved so far and what are the challenges ahead of us. We present the main principles, methods, and building blocks of the approach, and then we illustrate it through two applications. The first one investigates the impact of entry in the mainframes segment of the computer industry. The second application studies the effect of different industrial policies in uncertain technological environments.
Keywords
History friendly models Industry evolution Computer industry Pharmaceutical industry Entry Industrial policyNotes
References
- Balland, P. A., Boschma, R., Crespo, J., & Rigby, D. L. (2018). Smart specialization policy in the European Union: Relatedness, knowledge complexity and regional diversification. Regional Studies. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2018.1437900. (forthcoming).Google Scholar
- Barca, F., McCann, P., & Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2012). The case for regional development intervention: Place-based versus place-neutral approaches. Journal of Regional Science, 52, 134–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Boschma, R., & Capone, G. (2015). Institutions and diversification: Related versus unrelated diversification in a Varieties of capitalism framework. Research Policy, 44, 1902–1914.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Brenner, T., Murmann, J. P. (2003). The use of simulations in developing robust knowledge about causal processes: Methodological considerations and an application to industrial evolution. Papers on Economics and Evolution #0303. Jena: Max Planck Institute.Google Scholar
- Brenner, T., & Murmann, J. P. (2016). Using simulation experiments to test historical explanations: The development of the German dye industry 1857–1913. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 26, 907–932.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Capone, G., Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2013). Are switching costs always effective in creating first-mover advantage? The moderating role of demand and technological regimes. Long Range Planning, 46, 348–368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Capone, G., Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2019). Spinoffs in context: Entry and performance across industries. Industrial and Corporate Change. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dty071. (forthcoming).Google Scholar
- Cortinovis, N., Xiao, J., Boschma, R., & van Oort, F. G. (2017). Quality of government and social capital as drivers of regional diversification in Europe. Journal of Economic Geography, 17, 1179–1208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cowan, R., & Foray, D. (2002). Evolutionary economics and the counterfactual threat: On the nature and role of counterfactual history as an empirical tool in economics. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 12, 539–562.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
- Dawid, H. (2006). Agent-based models of innovation and technological change. In L. Tesfatsion & K. Judd (Eds.), Handbook of computational economics. Agent-based computational economics (Vol. 2, pp. 1235–1272). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
- Dosi, G., & Marengo, L. (2016). The dynamics of organizational structures and performances under diverging distributions of knowledge and different power structures. Journal of Institutional Economics, 11, 535–559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dosi, G., Pereira, M., Roventini, A., Virgillito, M. E. (2018). The labour-augmented K S model: A laboratory for the analysis of institutional and policy regimes. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3232487. Accessed 24 Jan 2019.
- Fagiolo, G., Guerini, M., Lamperti, F., Moneta, A., & Roventini, A. (2019). Validation of agent-based models in economics and finance. In C. Beisbart & N. J. Saam (Eds.), Computer simulation validation. Fundamental concepts, methodological frameworks, and philosophical perspectives. Cham, CH: Springer.Google Scholar
- Fontana, R., & Zirulia, L. (2015). “…then came Cisco, and the rest is history”: A history friendly model of the local area networking industry. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 25, 875–899.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Foray, D., David, P. A., Hall, B. (2009). Smart specialization: The concept. knowledge for growth, prospects for science, technology and innovation, Report, EUR24047, European Union.Google Scholar
- Garavaglia, C. (2010). Modelling industrial dynamics with “History-friendly” simulations. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 21, 258–275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Garavaglia, C., Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2006). Entry, market structure and innovation in a history-friendly model of the evolution of the pharmaceutical industry. In M. Mazzucato & G. Dosi (Eds.), Knowledge accumulation and industry evolution. The case of pharma-biotech (pp. 234–265). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Garavaglia, C., Malerba, F., Orsenigo, L., & Pezzoni, M. (2013). A simulation model of the evolution of the Pharmaceutical industry: A history friendly model. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 16(4), 5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Grabner, C. (2016). Agent-based computational models—a formal heuristic for institutionalist pattern modelling? Journal of Institutional Economics, 12, 241–261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Grazzini, J., & Richiardi, M. (2015). Estimation of ergodic agent-based models by simulated minimum distance. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 51, 148–165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Grazzini, J., Richiardi, M., & Tsionas, M. (2017). Bayesian estimation of agent-based models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 77, 26–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Guerini, M., & Moneta, A. (2017). A method for agent-based models validation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 82, 125–141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hausmann, R., & Rodrik, D. (2003). Economic development as self-discovery. Journal of Development Economics, 72, 603–633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kim, C. W., & Lee, K. (2003). Innovation, technological regimes and organizational selection in industry evolution: A ‘history friendly model’ of the DRAM industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 12, 1195–1221. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/12.6.1195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Klepper, S. (2002). The capabilities of new firms and the evolution of the US automobile industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11, 645–666.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Klepper, S. (2016). Experimental capitalism: The nanoeconomics of American high-tech industries. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
- Lamperti, F., Roventini, A., & Sani, A. (2018). Agent-based model calibration using machine learning surrogates. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 90, 366–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Landini, F., Lee, K., & Malerba, F. (2017). A history-friendly model of the successive changes in industrial leadership and the catch-up by latecomers. Research Policy, 46, 431–446. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.09.005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Landini, F., & Malerba, F. (2017). Public policy and catching up by developing countries in global industries: A simulation model. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 41, 927–960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Lee, K. (2013). Schumpeterian analysis of economic catch-up: Knowledge, path-creation, and the middle-income trap. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Levinthal, D. (1997). Adaptation on rugged landscapes. Management Science, 43, 934–950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Li, D., Capone, G., & Malerba, F. (2019). The “Long March” to catch-up: A history-friendly model of China’s mobile communications industry. Research Policy, 48, 649–664. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2018.10.019.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F. (2002). Sectoral systems of innovation and production. Research Policy, 31, 247–261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., & Adams, P. (2014). Sectoral systems of innovation. In M. Dodgson, D. Gann, & N. Phillips (Eds.), The oxford handbook of innovation management (pp. 183–203). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
- Malerba, F., & Nelson, R. R. (Eds.). (2012). Economic development as a learning process: variation across sectoral systems. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
- Malerba, F., Nelson, R. R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. G. (1999). ‘History-friendly’ models of industry evolution: The computer industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 8, 3–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., Nelson, R. R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. G. (2001). Competition and industrial policies in a history-friendly model of the evolution of the computer industry. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19, 635–664.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., Nelson, R. R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. G. (2007). Demand, innovation, and the dynamics of market structure: The role of experimental users and diverse preferences. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 17, 371–399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., Nelson, R. R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. G. (2008a). Vertical integration and disintegration of computer firms: A history-friendly model of the coevolution of the computer and semiconductor industries. Industrial and Corporate Change, 17, 197–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., Nelson, R. R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. G. (2008b). Public policies and changing boundaries of firms in a history-friendly model of the co-evolution of the computer and semiconductors industries. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 67, 355–380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., Nelson, R. R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. G. (2016). Innovation and the evolution of industries: History friendly models. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2002). Innovation and market structure in the dynamics of the pharmaceutical industry and biotechnology: Towards a history-friendly model. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11, 667–703.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2010). User-producer relation, innovation and the evolution of market structures under alternative contractual regimes. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 21, 26–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Malerba, F., Yoon, M. (2011). Modelling the evolution of firm boundaries: A history-friendly model of the emergence of the fabless ecosystem. Working Paper, Milan and Seoul.Google Scholar
- Mazzucato, M. (2013). The entrepreneurial state: debunking public vs. private sector myths. London: Anthem Press.Google Scholar
- Mazzucato, M., Cimoli, M., Dosi, G., Stiglitz, J., Landesmann, M., Pianta, M., et al. (2015). Forum: Which industrial policy does Europe need? Intereconomics, 50(3), 120–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Mowery, D. C., & Nelson, R. R. (Eds.). (1999). Sources of industrial leadership: studies of seven industries. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- Nelson, R. R., Dosi, G., Helfat, C. E., Pyka, A., Winter, S. G., Saviotti, P. P., et al. (2018). Modern evolutionary economics. An overview. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
- Pereira, M., & Dequech, D. (2015). A History-Friendly Model of the Internet Access Market: The Case of Brazil. In A. Pyka & J. Foster (Eds.), The evolution of economic and innovation systems (pp. 579–610). New York: Springer.Google Scholar
- Pianta, M. (2014). An industrial policy for Europe. Seoul Journal of Economics, 27, 277–305.Google Scholar
- Rodrik, D. (2004). Industrial policy for the twenty-first century. Working paper, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University.Google Scholar
- Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2002). Is subsidizing entry an optimal policy? Industrial and Corporate Change, 11, 39–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Simon, H. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69, 99–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tesfatsion, L. (2002). Agent-based computational economics: Growing economies from the bottom up. Artificial Life, 8, 55–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Windrum, P., Fagiolo, G., & Moneta, A. (2007). Empirical validation of agent-based models: Alternatives and prospects. Journal of Artificial Societies and Simulation, 10(2), 8.Google Scholar
Copyright information
© Eurasia Business and Economics Society 2019