A macroscopic portfolio model: from rational agents to bounded rationality
- 11 Downloads
Abstract
We introduce a microscopic model of interacting financial agents, where each agent is characterized by two portfolios; money invested in bonds and money invested in stocks. Furthermore, each agent is faced with an optimization problem in order to determine the optimal asset allocation. Thus, we consider a differential game since all agents aim to invest optimal and we introduce the concept of Nash equilibrium solutions to ensure the existence of a solution. Especially, we denote an agent who solves this Nash equilibrium exactly a rational agent. As next step we use model predictive control to approximate the control problem. This enables us to derive a precise mathematical characterization of the degree of rationality of a financial agent. This is a novel concept in portfolio optimization and can be regarded as a general approach. In a second step we consider the case of a fully myopic agent, where we can solve the optimal investment decision of investors explicitly. We select the running cost to be the expected missed revenue of an agent which are determined by a combination of a fundamentalist and chartist strategy. Then we derive the mean field limit of the microscopic model in order to obtain a macroscopic portfolio model. The novelty in comparison to existent macroeconomic models in literature is that our model is derived from microeconomic dynamics. The resulting portfolio model is a three dimensional ODE system which enables us to derive analytical results. The conducted simulations reveal that the model shares many dynamical properties with existing models in literature. Thus, our model is able to replicate the most prominent features of financial markets, namely booms and crashes. In the case of random fundamental prices the model is even able to reproduce fat tails in logarithmic stock price return data. Mathematically, the model can be regarded as the moment model of the recently introduced mesoscopic kinetic portfolio model (Trimborn et al. in Portfolio optimization and model predictive con trol: a kinetic approach, arXiv:1711.03291, 2017).
Keywords
Portfolio optimization Model predictive control Stock market Bounded rationality Crashes BoomsJEL Classification
G11 G12Notes
Acknowledgements
Torsten Trimborn gratefully acknowledges funding by the Hans-Böckler-Stiftung.
References
- 1.Albi, G., Pareschi, L., Zanella, M.: Boltzmann-type control of opinion consensus through leaders. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. Lond. A: Math., Phys. Eng. Sci. 372(2028), 20140138 (2014)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 2.Anand, K., Kirman, A., Marsili, M.: Epidemics of rules, information aggregation failure and market crashes. https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00545144 (2010)
- 3.Beja, A., Goldman, M.B.: On the dynamic behavior of prices in disequilibrium. J. Financ. 35(2), 235–248 (1980)Google Scholar
- 4.Bertsimas, D., Pachamanova, D.: Robust multiperiod portfolio management in the presence of transaction costs. Comput. Oper. Res. 35(1), 3–17 (2008)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 5.Breeden, D.T., Litzenberger, R.H.: Prices of state-contingent claims implicit in option prices. J. Bus. 51, 621–651 (1978)Google Scholar
- 6.Bressan, A.: Noncooperative differential games. Milan J. Math. 79(2), 357–427 (2011)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 7.Brock, W.A., Hommes, C.H.: A rational route to randomness. Econom. J. Econom. Soc. 65, 1059–1095 (1997)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 8.Brock, W.A., Hommes, C.H.: Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 22(8), 1235–1274 (1998)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 9.Brown, D.J., Lewis, L.M.: Myopic economic agents. Econom. J. Econom. Soc. 49, 359–368 (1981)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 10.Camacho, E.F., Alba, C.B.: Model Predictive Control. Springer, Berlin (2013)Google Scholar
- 11.Chiarella, C.: The dynamics of speculative behaviour. Ann. Oper. Res. 37(1), 101–123 (1992)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 12.Chiarella, C., He, X.-Z.: Heterogeneous beliefs, risk and learning in a simple asset pricing model. Comput. Econ. 19(1), 95–132 (2002)zbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 13.Conlisk, J.: Why bounded rationality? J. Econ. Lit. 34(2), 669–700 (1996)Google Scholar
- 14.Cont, R., Bouchaud, J.-P.: Herd behavior and aggregate fluctuations in financial markets. Macroecon. Dyn. 4(02), 170–196 (2000)zbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 15.Day, R.H., Huang, W.: Bulls, bears and market sheep. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 14(3), 299–329 (1990)Google Scholar
- 16.Duffie, D., Zame, W.: The consumption-based capital asset pricing model. Econom. J. Econom. Soc. 57, 1279–1297 (1989)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 17.Egenter, E., Lux, T., Stauffer, D.: Finite-size effects in monte carlo simulations of two stock market models. Phys. A: Stat. Mech. Appl. 268(1), 250–256 (1999)Google Scholar
- 18.Fama, E.F.: The behavior of stock-market prices. J. Bus. 38(1), 34–105 (1965)Google Scholar
- 19.Franke, R., Westerhoff, F.: Structural stochastic volatility in asset pricing dynamics: estimation and model contest. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 36(8), 1193–1211 (2012)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 20.Golse, F.: On the dynamics of large particle systems in the mean field limit. Macroscopic and Large Scale Phenomena: Coarse Graining. Mean Field Limits and Ergodicity, pp. 1–144. Springer, Cham (2016)Google Scholar
- 21.Gros, D.: The effectiveness of capital controls: implications for monetary autonomy in the presence of incomplete market separation. Staff Pap. 34(4), 621–642 (1987)Google Scholar
- 22.Grüne, L., Pannek, J., Seehafer, M., Worthmann, K.: Analysis of unconstrained nonlinear mpc schemes with time varying control horizon. SIAM J. Control Optim. 48(8), 4938–4962 (2010)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 23.Grune, L., Rantzer, A.: On the infinite horizon performance of receding horizon controllers. IEEE Trans. Autom. Control 53(9), 2100–2111 (2008)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 24.Hommes, C.H.: Modeling the stylized facts in finance through simple nonlinear adaptive systems. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 99(suppl 3), 7221–7228 (2002)Google Scholar
- 25.Hommes, C.H.: Heterogeneous agent models in economics and finance. Handb. Comput. Econ. 2, 1109–1186 (2006)Google Scholar
- 26.Jensen, M.C., Black, F., Scholes, M.S.: The capital asset pricing model: some empirical tests. In: M. C. Jensen (ed.) Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, Praeger Publishers inc. (1972)Google Scholar
- 27.Kahneman, D.: Maps of bounded rationality: psychology for behavioral economics. Am. Econ. Rev. 93(5), 1449–1475 (2003)Google Scholar
- 28.Kahneman, D., Tversky, A.: Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econom. J. Econom. Soc. 47, 263–291 (1979)zbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 29.Kirk, D.E.: Optimal Control Theory: An Introduction. Springer, Berlin (1970)Google Scholar
- 30.Kirman, A.: The crisis in economic theory. Rivista Italiana Degli Economisti 16(1), 9–36 (2011)Google Scholar
- 31.Lehmann, B.N.: Fads, martingales, and market efficiency. Q. J. Econ. 105(1), 1–28 (1990)Google Scholar
- 32.Levy, M., Levy, H., Solomon, S.: A microscopic model of the stock market: cycles, booms, and crashes. Econ. Lett. 45(1), 103–111 (1994)zbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 33.Lintner, J.: Security prices, risk, and maximal gains from diversification. J. Financ. 20(4), 587–615 (1965)Google Scholar
- 34.Lo, A.W.: The adaptive markets hypothesis: market efficiency from an evolutionary perspective. J Portf Manag 30th Anniv. 30(5), 15–29 (2004)Google Scholar
- 35.Lux, T.: Herd behaviour, bubbles and crashes. Econ. J. 105, 881–896 (1995)Google Scholar
- 36.Lux, T. et al: Stochastic behavioral asset pricing models and the stylized facts. Technical report, Economics working paper/Christian-Albrechts-Universität Kiel, Department of Economics, (2008)Google Scholar
- 37.Lux, T., Marchesi, M.: Scaling and criticality in a stochastic multi-agent model of a financial market. Nature 397(6719), 498–500 (1999)Google Scholar
- 38.Malkiel, B.G.: The efficient market hypothesis and its critics. J. Econ. Perspect. 17(1), 59–82 (2003)Google Scholar
- 39.Mantel, R.R., et al.: On the characterization of aggregate excess demand. J. Econ. Theory 7(3), 348–353 (1974)Google Scholar
- 40.Markowitz, H.: Portfolio selection. J. Financ. 7(1), 77–91 (1952)Google Scholar
- 41.Merton, R.C.: Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: the continuous-time case. Rev. Econ. Stat. 51, 247–257 (1969)Google Scholar
- 42.Merton, R.C.: Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time model. In: Stochastic Optimization Models in Finance, pp. 621–661. Elsevier, Amsterdam (1975)Google Scholar
- 43.Michalska, H., Mayne, D.Q.: Receding horizon control of nonlinear systems. In: Proceedings of the 28th IEEE Conference on Decision and Control, 1989, pp. 107–108. IEEE, (1989)Google Scholar
- 44.Mitchell, J.E., Braun, S.: Rebalancing an investment portfolio in the presence of convex transaction costs, including market impact costs. Optim. Methods Softw. 28(3), 523–542 (2013)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 45.Mossin, J.: Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econom.: J. Econom. Soc. 34, 768–783 (1966)Google Scholar
- 46.Niehans, J.: The international allocation of savings with quadratic transaction (or risk) costs. J. Int. Money Financ. 11(3), 222–234 (1992)Google Scholar
- 47.Odean, T.: Volume, volatility, price, and profit when all traders are above average. J. Financ. 53(6), 1887–1934 (1998)Google Scholar
- 48.Ross, S.A.: The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. In: Handbook of the Fundamentals of Financial Decision Making: Part I, pp. 11–30. World Scientific, Singapore (2013)Google Scholar
- 49.Rubinstein, M.: The valuation of uncertain income streams and the pricing of options. Bell J. Econ. 7, 407–425 (1976)MathSciNetGoogle Scholar
- 50.Sharpe, W.F.: Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J. Financ. 19(3), 425–442 (1964)Google Scholar
- 51.Shiller, R.J.: From efficient markets theory to behavioral finance. J. Econ. Perspect. 17(1), 83–104 (2003)Google Scholar
- 52.Simon, H.A.: A behavioral model of rational choice. Q. J. Econ. 69, 99–118 (1955)Google Scholar
- 53.Sonnenschein, H.: Market excess demand functions. Econom.: J. Econom. Soc. 40, 549–563 (1972)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar
- 54.Sontag, E.D.: Mathematical Control Theory: Deterministic Finite Dimensional Systems, vol. 6. Springer, Berlin (2013)Google Scholar
- 55.Stanley, H.E.: Phase Transitions and Critical Phenomena. Clarendon Press, Oxford (1971)Google Scholar
- 56.Treynor, J.L.: Market value, time, and risk. (1961)Google Scholar
- 57.Trimborn, T., Otte, P., Cramer, S., Beikirch, M., Pabich, E., Frank, M.: Sabcemm- a simulator for agent-based computational economic market models. arXiv preprint arXiv:1801.01811, (2018)
- 58.Trimborn, T., Pareschi, L., Frank, M.: Portfolio optimization and model predictive control: a kinetic approach. arXiv preprint arXiv:1711.03291, (2017)
- 59.Walras, L.: Études d’économie politique appliquée:(Théorie de la production de la richesse sociale). In: Rouge, F. (ed.), Paris (1898)Google Scholar
- 60.Zhou, W.-X., Sornette, D.: Self-organizing ising model of financial markets. Eur. Phys. J. B 55(2), 175–181 (2007)MathSciNetzbMATHGoogle Scholar