Advertisement

Theory and Decision

, Volume 87, Issue 1, pp 87–122 | Cite as

Individual vs. group decision-making: an experiment on dynamic choice under risk and ambiguity

  • Enrica Carbone
  • Konstantinos GeorgalosEmail author
  • Gerardo Infante
Article
  • 215 Downloads

Abstract

This paper focuses on the comparison of individual and group decision-making, in a stochastic inter-temporal problem in two decision environments, namely risk and ambiguity. Using a consumption/saving laboratory experiment, we investigate behaviour in four treatments: (1) individual choice under risk; (2) group choice under risk; (3) individual choice under ambiguity and (4) group choice under ambiguity. Comparing decisions within and between decision environments, we find an anti-symmetric pattern. While individuals are choosing on average closer to the theoretical optimal predictions, compared to groups in the risk treatments, groups tend to deviate less under ambiguity. Within decision environments, individuals deviate more when they choose under ambiguity, while groups are better planners under ambiguity rather than under risk. Our results extend the often observed pattern of individuals (groups) behaving more optimally under risk (ambiguity), to its dynamic dimension.

Keywords

Risk Ambiguity Inter-temporal optimisation Group decision-making Learning Experiment 

Notes

Supplementary material

References

  1. Ahn, D., Choi, S., Gale, D., & Kariv, S. (2014). Estimating ambiguity aversion in a portfolio choice experiment. Quantitative Economics, 5(2), 195–223.Google Scholar
  2. Attanasi, G., Gollier, C., Montesano, A., & Pace, N. (2014). Eliciting ambiguity aversion in unknown and in compound lotteries: A smooth ambiguity model experimental study. Theory and Decision, 77, 485–530.Google Scholar
  3. Baillon, A., Bleichrodt, H., Keskin, U., L’Haridon, O., & Li, C. (2018). Learning under ambiguity: An experiment using initial public offerings on a stock market. Management Science, 64(5), 2181–2198.Google Scholar
  4. Baillon, A., Bleichrodt, H., Liu, N., & Wakker, P. (2016). Group decision rules and group rationality under risk. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 52(2), 99–116.Google Scholar
  5. Baker, R., Laury, S., & Williams, A. (2008). Comparing small-group and individual behavior in lottery-choice experiments. Southern Economic Journal, 75(2), 367–382.Google Scholar
  6. Ballinger, T., Hudson, E., Karkoviata, L., & Wilcox, N. (2011). Saving behavior and cognitive abilities. Experimental Economics, 14(3), 349–374.Google Scholar
  7. Ballinger, T. P., Palumbo, M. G., & Wilcox, N. T. (2003). Precautionary saving and social learning across generations: An experiment. The Economic Journal, 113(490), 920–947.Google Scholar
  8. Berg, J., Daley, L., Dichaut, J., & O’Brien, J. (1986). Controlling preferences for lotteries on units of experimental exchange. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(2), 281–306.Google Scholar
  9. Bougheas, S., Nieboer, J., & Sefton, M. (2013). Risk-taking in social settings: Group and peer effects. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 92, 273–283.Google Scholar
  10. Brown, A. L., Chua, Z. E., & Camerer, C. F. (2009). Learning and visceral temptation in dynamic saving experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(1), 197–231.Google Scholar
  11. Brunette, M., Cabantous, L., & Couture, S. (2015). Are individuals more risk and ambiguity averse in a group environment or alone? Results from an experimental study. Theory and Decision, 78(3), 357–376.Google Scholar
  12. Caballero, R. (1990). Consumption puzzles and precautionary savings. Journal of Monetary Economics, 25, 113–136.Google Scholar
  13. Camerer, C., & Weber, M. (1992). Recent developments in modeling preferences: Uncertainty and ambiguity. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 325–370.Google Scholar
  14. Campanale, C. (2011). Learning, ambiguity and life-cycle portfolio allocation. Review of Economic Dynamics, 14(2), 339–367.Google Scholar
  15. Carbone, E. (2005). Demographics and behaviour. Experimental Economics, 8, 217–232.Google Scholar
  16. Carbone, E., & Duffy, J. (2014). Lifecycle consumption plans, social learning and external habits: Experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 106, 413–427.Google Scholar
  17. Carbone, E., & Hey, J. D. (2004). The effect of unemployment on consumption: An experimental analysis. The Economic Journal, 114(497), 660–683.Google Scholar
  18. Carbone, E., & Infante, G. (2014). Comparing behavior under risk and under ambiguity in a lifecycle experiment. Theory and Decision, 57, 313–322.Google Scholar
  19. Carbone, E., & Infante, G. (2015). Are groups better planners than individuals? An experimental analysis. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 57, 112–119.Google Scholar
  20. Carlsson, F., He, H., Martinsson, P., Qin, P., & Sutter, M. (2012). Household decision making in rural China: Using experiments to estimate the influences of spouses. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 84(2), 525–536.Google Scholar
  21. Charness, G., Karni, E., & Levin, D. (2007). Individual and group decision making under risk: An experimental study of Bayesian updating and violations of first-order stochastic dominance. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 35(2), 129–148.Google Scholar
  22. Charness, G., Karni, E., & Levin, D. (2010). On the conjunction fallacy in probability judgment: New experimental evidence regarding linda. Games and Economic Behavior, 68(2), 551–556.Google Scholar
  23. Charness, G., Karni, E., & Levin, D. (2013). Ambiguity attitudes and social interactions: An experimental investigation. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 46(1), 1–25.Google Scholar
  24. Charness, G., & Sutter, M. (2012). Groups make better self-interested decisions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(3), 157–76.Google Scholar
  25. Cohen, M., Gilboa, I., & Schmeidler, D. (2000). An experimental study of updating ambiguous beliefs. Risk Decision and Policy, 5(2), 123–133.Google Scholar
  26. Conte, A., & Hey, J. (2013). Assessing multiple prior models of behaviour under ambiguity. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 46(2), 113–132.Google Scholar
  27. Cooper, D., & Kagel, J. (2005). Are two heads better than one? Team versus individual play in signaling games. American Economic Review, 95(3), 477–509.Google Scholar
  28. Curley, S., Yates, F., & Abrams, R. (1986). Psychological sources of ambiguity avoidance. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 38(2), 230–256.Google Scholar
  29. Denant-Boemont, L., Diecidue, E., & l’Haridon, O. (2016). Patience and time consistency in collective decisions. Experimental Economics (page forthcoming).Google Scholar
  30. Dominiak, A., Dürsch, P., & Lefort, J. (2012). A dynamic ellsberg urn experiment. Games and Economic Behavior, 75, 625–638.Google Scholar
  31. Duffy, J. (2014). Macroeconomics: A survey of laboratory research. Technical report, University of California.Google Scholar
  32. Dutt, V., Arló-Costa, H., Helzner, J., & Gonzalez, C. (2014). The description-experience gap in risky and ambiguous gambles. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 27, 316–327.Google Scholar
  33. Ellsberg, D. (1961). Risk, ambiguity and the savage axioms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75, 643–669.Google Scholar
  34. Epstein, L., Noor, J., & Sandroni, A. (2010). Non-bayesian learning. The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, 10(1), 1–20.Google Scholar
  35. Epstein, L., & Schneider, M. (2007). Learning under ambiguity. Review of Economic Studies, 74(4), 1275–1303.Google Scholar
  36. Etner, J., Jeleva, M., & Tallon, J. (2012). Decision theory under ambiguity. Journal of Economic Surveys, 26(2), 234–270.Google Scholar
  37. Feltovich, N., & Ejebu, O. (2014). Do positional goods inhibit saving? Evidence from a life-cycle experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 107, 440–454. (Empirical Behavioral Finance).Google Scholar
  38. Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.Google Scholar
  39. Gillet, J., Schram, A., & Sonnemans, J. (2009). The tragedy of the commons revisited: The importance of group decision-making. Journal of Public Economics, 93(5–6), 785–797.Google Scholar
  40. Güney, c, & Newell, B. (2015). Overcoming ambiguity aversion through experience. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 28, 188–199.Google Scholar
  41. Halevy, Y. (2007). Ellsberg revisited: An experimental study. Econometrica, 75(2), 503–536.Google Scholar
  42. Hey, J., & Pace, N. (2014). The explanatory and predictive power of non two-stage-probability models of decision making under ambiguity. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 49(1), 1–29.Google Scholar
  43. Hey, J. D., & Dardanoni, V. (1988). Optimal consumption under uncertainty: An experimental investigation. The Economic Journal, 98(390), 105–116.Google Scholar
  44. Jackson, M. O., & Yariv, L. (2014). Present bias and collective dynamic choice in the lab. American Economic Review, 104(12), 4184–4204.Google Scholar
  45. Keck, S., Diecidue, E., & Budescu, D. (2014). Group decisions under ambiguity: Convergence to neutrality. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 103, 60–71.Google Scholar
  46. Keller, R., Sarin, R., & Sounderpandian, J. (2007). An examination of ambiguity aversion: Are two heads better than one? Judgment and Decision Making, 2(6), 390–397.Google Scholar
  47. Klibanoff, P., Marinacci, M., & Mukerji, S. (2005). A smooth model of decision making under ambiguity. Econometrica, 73(6), 1849–1892.Google Scholar
  48. Kugler, T., Kausel, E. E., & Kocher, M. G. (2012). Are group more rational than individuals? A review of interactive decision making in groups. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews Cognitive Science, 3(4), 471–482.Google Scholar
  49. Lahno, A. M. (2014). Social anchor effects in decision-making under ambiguity. Discussion Papers in Economics 20960, University of Munich, Department of Economics.Google Scholar
  50. Levati, V., Napel, S., & Soraperra, I. (2016). Collective choices under ambiguity. Group Decision and Negotiation, 26, 1–17.Google Scholar
  51. Marinacci, M. (2002). Learning from ambiguous urns. Statistical Papers, 43, 145–151.Google Scholar
  52. Masclet, D., Colombier, N., Denant-Boemont, L., & Lohéac, Y. (2009). Group and individual risk preferences: A lottery-choice experiment with self-employed and salaried workers. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 70(3), 470–484. (Field Experiments in Economics).Google Scholar
  53. Meissner, T. (2015). Intertemporal consumption and debt aversion: An experimental study. Experimental Economics, 19, 1–18.Google Scholar
  54. Muthukrishnan, A., Wathieu, L., & Xu, J. (2009). Ambiguity aversion and the preference for established brands. Management Science, 55(12), 1933–1941.Google Scholar
  55. Nicholls, N., Romm, A. T., & Zimper, A. (2015). The impact of statistical learning on violations of the sure-thing principle. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 50(2), 97–115.Google Scholar
  56. Peijnenburg (2015). Life-cycle asset allocation with ambiguity aversion and learning. Working paper.Google Scholar
  57. R Core Team. (2013). R: A language and environment for statistical computing. Vienna: R Foundation for Statistical Computing.Google Scholar
  58. Savage, L. (1954). The foundations of statistics. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  59. Schotter, A., & Braunstein, Y. (1981). Economic search: An experinental study. Economic In, 19(1), 1–25.Google Scholar
  60. Shapiro, J. (2010). Discounting for you, me and we: Time preference in groups and pairs. mimeo.Google Scholar
  61. Shupp, R., & Williams, A. (2008). Risk preference differentials of small groups and individuals. The Economic Journal, 118(525), 258–283.Google Scholar
  62. Stahl, D. (2014). Heterogeneity of ambiguity preferences. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(5), 609–617.Google Scholar
  63. Trautmann, S., & van de Kuilen, G. (2015). Wiley Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making, chapter Ambiguity Attitudes (pp. 89–116). Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  64. Trautmann, S., Vieider, F., & Wakker, P. (2008). Causes of ambiguity aversion: Known versus unknown preferences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 36(3), 225–243.Google Scholar
  65. Viscusi, W. (1985). A Bayesian perspective on biases in risk perception. Economics Letters, 17(1–2), 59–62.Google Scholar
  66. Viscusi, W., & O’Connor, J. (1984). Adaptive responses to chemical labeling: Are workers Bayesian decision makers? The American Economic Review, 74(5), 942–956.Google Scholar
  67. Zhang, J., & Casari, M. (2012). How groups reach agreement in risky choices. Economic Inquiry, 50(2), 502–515.Google Scholar
  68. Zimper, A., & Ludwig, A. (2009). On attitude polarization under Bayesian learning with non-additive beliefs. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 39(2), 181–212.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Political Sciences “Jean Monnet”University of Campania “Luigi Vanvitelli”CasertaItaly
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsLancaster University Management SchoolLancasterUK
  3. 3.TorontoCanada

Personalised recommendations