Advertisement

Improving the peer review process: a proposed market system

  • Paul Frijters
  • Benno TorglerEmail author
Article

Abstract

The current peer review system suffers from two key problems: promotion of an in-crowd whose methods, opinions and innovations it protects; and failure to represent the opinions and interests of non-peer clients. As a result, whole disciplines orient themselves toward navel-gazing research questions of little import to society or even science as a whole, and new methods and concepts must be unusually persuasive to break through. We thus suggest a more efficient and integrity-preserving system based on an open two-sided market in which buyers and sellers of peer review services would both be subject to a set of recursive quality indicators. We lay out key features we think would be important to reduce the opportunities for gaming and that improve the signals about the societal value of a contribution. Our suggestions include a level of reward offered by the author of a paper to get refereed and a level of desired quality of the referee. They include randomly selecting from a group of referees that express a willingness to accept the offered contract. They include the possibility that papers are put up by non-authors for peer-review for assessment on different criteria, such as societal relevance. And they finally include the possibility that referee reports themselves become refereed by other referees. What we envisage is that such an open market in which all elements are subject to peer review will over time lead to specialized reviewers in different criteria, and more useful signals about the nature and quality of any individual piece of work. Our incentivized market set-up would both professionalize the peer review process and make it completely transparent, an innovation long overdue.

References

  1. Alberts, B., Hanson, B., & Kelner, K. L. (2008). Reviewing peer review. Science, 321, 15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Arns, M. (2014). Open access is tiring out peer reviewers. Nature, 515, 467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Couzin-Frankel, J. (2013). Secretive and subjective, peer review proves resistant to study. Science, 341, 1331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. DeCoursey, T. (2006). Perspective: The pros and cons of open peer review. Nature http://blogs.nature.com/peer-to-peer/2006/06/perspective_the_pros_and_cons.html
  5. Groves, T. (2006). Quality and value: How can we get the best out of peer review? Nature http://blogs.nature.com/peer-to-peer/2006/06/quality_and_value_how_can_we_g.html. Accessed 13 Mar 2016.
  6. Harly, D. (2013). Scholarly communication: Cultural contexts. Evolving Models Science, 342, 80–82.Google Scholar
  7. Jennings, C.G. (2006). Quality and value: The true purpose of peer review? Nature http://blogs.nature.com/peer-to-peer/2006/06/quality_and_value_the_true_pur.html
  8. Koonin, E., Landweber, L., Lipman, D. & Dignon, R. (2006). Systems: Reviving a culture of scientific debate. Nature. http://blogs.nature.com/peer-to-peer/2006/06/systems_reviving_a_culture_of_1.html. Accessed 13 Mar 2016.
  9. Lawrence, P. A. (2003). The politics of publication. Nature, 422, 259–261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Mervis, J. (2014). Peering into the peer. Review Science, 343, 596.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Akadémiai Kiadó, Budapest, Hungary 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Centre for Economic PerformanceLondon School of Economics and Political ScienceLondonUK
  2. 2.School of Economics and FinanceQueensland University of TechnologyBrisbaneAustralia
  3. 3.Centre for Behavioural Economics, Society and Technology (BEST)Queensland University of TechnologyBrisbaneAustralia
  4. 4.Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts (CREMA)ZurichSwitzerland

Personalised recommendations