Advertisement

Review of Industrial Organization

, Volume 54, Issue 3, pp 509–541 | Cite as

Merger Analysis in Two-Sided Markets: The Belgian Newspaper Industry

  • Patrick Van Cayseele
  • Stijn VanormelingenEmail author
Article
  • 170 Downloads

Abstract

This paper builds a structural model for both advertising and readers’ demand in the Belgian newspaper industry, taking into account cross network effects that exist between advertisers and newspaper readers We combine our parameter estimates with the publishers’ first-order conditions to simulate the impact of a merger. We find a limited impact of the merger on reader and advertiser welfare. The effect on welfare is easily offset by possible efficiency gains. We compare the simulation outcome with the actual outcomes and find—in line with the predictions—no clear aggregate effect of the merger. The responses of individual newspapers, however, differ from the simulation.

Keywords

Merger simulation Two-sided markets Newspapers Demand estimation 

JEL Classification

L11 L82 C23 

Notes

Acknowledgements

We thank the editor, two anonymous referees, Filip Abraham, Anneleen Forrier, Lisa George, Joep Konings, Jo Van Biesebroeck, Ambarish Chandra, Gregory Crawford, Jan De Loecker, Lapo Filistrucchi, Damiaan Persyn, Charles Romeo, Ricardo Ribeiro, John Sutton, Pasquale Schiraldi, Frank Verboven, and participants at the IIOC Conference in Savannah, EARIE Conference in Valencia, MIE Spring Camp at KU Leuven, LSE Work in Progress Seminar Series, and IESE SP-SP Luch Seminar Series for useful comments and suggestions.

Compliance with Ethical Standards

Conflict of interest

Patrick Van Cayseele has been an expert member of the Belgian antitrust authority and was involved in consulting practice in many merger cases in the Media industry.

References

  1. Affeldt, P., Filistrucchi, L., & Klein, T. J. (2013). Upward pricing pressure in two-sided markets. The Economic Journal, 123(572), F505–F523.Google Scholar
  2. Argentesi, E., & Filistrucchi, L. (2007). Estimating market power in a two-sided market: The case of newspapers. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22(7), 1247–1266.Google Scholar
  3. Armstrong, M. (2006). Competition in two-sided markets. The RAND Journal of Economics, 37(3), 668–691.Google Scholar
  4. Ashenfelter, O., & Hosken, D. (2010). The effect of mergers on consumer prices: Evidence from five mergers on the enforcement margin. The Journal of Law and Economics, 53(3), 417–466.Google Scholar
  5. Berry, S. T. (1994). Estimating discrete-choice models of product differentiation. The RAND Journal of Economics, 25(2), 242–262.Google Scholar
  6. Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., & Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica, 63(4), 841–890.Google Scholar
  7. Bjornerstedt, J., & Verboven, F. (2016). Does merger simulation work? Evidence from the Swedish Analgesics market. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 8(3), 125–64.Google Scholar
  8. Brenkers, R., & Verboven, F. (2006). Liberalizing a distribution system: The European car market. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(1), 216–251.Google Scholar
  9. Budzinski, O., & Ruhmer, I. (2010). Merger simulation in competition policy: A survey. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 6(2), 277–319.Google Scholar
  10. Busse, M., & Rysman, M. (2005). Competition and price discrimination in yellow pages advertising. The RAND Journal of Economics, 36(2), 378–390.Google Scholar
  11. Chandra, A., & Collard-Wexler, A. (2009). Mergers in two-sided markets: An application to the Canadian newspaper industry. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 18(4), 1045–1070.Google Scholar
  12. De Bens, E., & Raeymaeckers, K. (2007). De Pers in België. Tielt: Lannoo Uitgeverij.Google Scholar
  13. Evans, D. S., & Noel, M. D. (2008). The analysis of mergers that involve multisided platform businesses. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 4(3), 32.Google Scholar
  14. Fan, Y. (2013). Ownership consolidation and product characteristics: A study of the US daily newspaper market. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1598–1628.Google Scholar
  15. Farrel, J., & Shapiro, C. (2010). Antitrust evaluation of horizontal mergers: An economic alternative to market definition. B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, 10(1), 1–39.Google Scholar
  16. Filistrucchi, L., Klein, T. J., & Michielsen, T. O. (2012). Assessing unilateral merger effects in a two-sided market: An application to the Dutch daily newspaper market. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 8(2), 297–329.Google Scholar
  17. George, L. (2007). What’s fit to print: The effect of ownership concentration on product variety in daily newspaper markets. Information Economics and Policy, 19(3–4), 285–303.Google Scholar
  18. Hausman, J., Leonard, G., & Zona, J. (1994). Competitive analysis with differentiated products. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 34, 423–446.Google Scholar
  19. Ivaldi, M., & Verboven, F. (2005). Quantifying the effects from horizontal mergers in European competition policy. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23(9–10), 669–691.Google Scholar
  20. Jeziorski, P. (2014a). Effects of mergers in two-sided markets: The US radio industry. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 6(4), 35–73.Google Scholar
  21. Jeziorski, P. (2014b). Estimation of cost efficiencies from mergers: Application to US radio. The RAND Journal of Economics, 45(4), 816–846.Google Scholar
  22. Kaiser, U., & Wright, J. (2006). Price structure in two-sided markets: Evidence from the magazine industry. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24(1), 1–28.Google Scholar
  23. MediaMarketing. (2004). Hoe Tabloid tot Modules Leidt. Media Marketing, 93. http://www.mm.be/nl/archief.php?id=231. Accessed 10 June 2005.
  24. Miller, N. H., Remer, M., Ryan, C., & Sheu, G. (2017). Upward pricing pressure as a predictor of merger price effects. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 52, 216–247.Google Scholar
  25. Nevo, A. (2000). Mergers with differentiated products: The case of the ready-to-eat cereal industry. RAND Journal of Economics, 31(3), 395–421.Google Scholar
  26. Nevo, A. (2001). Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry. Econometrica, 69(2), 307–342.Google Scholar
  27. Pinkse, J., & Slade, M. E. (2004). Mergers, brand competition, and the price of a pint. European Economic Review, 48(3), 617–643.Google Scholar
  28. Rochet, J.-C., & Tirole, J. (2003). Platform competition in two-sided markets. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(4), 990–1029.Google Scholar
  29. Rysman, M. (2004). Competition between networks: A study of the market for yellow pages. Review of Economic Studies, 71(247), 483–512.Google Scholar
  30. Shea, J. (1997). Instrument relevance in multivariate linear models: A simple measure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(2), 348–352.Google Scholar
  31. Sokullu, S. (2015). Network effects in the German magazine industry. Economics Letters, 143, 77–79.Google Scholar
  32. Staiger, D., & Stock, J. (1997). Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica, 65(3), 557–586.Google Scholar
  33. Verboven, F. (1996). International price discrimination in the European car market. RAND Journal of Economics, 27(2), 240–268.Google Scholar
  34. Wilbur, K. C. (2008). A two-sided, empirical model of television advertising and viewing markets. Marketing Science, 27(3), 356–378.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.LICOS and CESKU LeuvenLouvainBelgium
  2. 2.ECON-CEDON and VIVESKU LeuvenBrusselsBelgium

Personalised recommendations