Advertisement

Quality & Quantity

, Volume 53, Issue 1, pp 529–551 | Cite as

Does centrality of importing countries affect export prices in the global trade?

  • Vittorio Carlei
  • Francesca Affortunato
  • Alessandro Marra
  • Marco Brogi
Article
  • 46 Downloads

Abstract

This study employs network analysis to explore whether and to what extent export prices vary with the relative position of importing (or destination) countries in the world trade network. We estimate a gravity model, where export prices are regressed on the relative position of destination countries in the network, GDP per capita, physical distance, contiguity, and common language. We employ three measures of centrality to account for different aspects of the position of destination markets in the trade network: in-degree centrality (to examine the extent to which a destination country is well supplied within the network); indirect centrality (to assess the exporting countries’ influence on a destination country); arch centrality (to estimate the relevance of importing markets for exporting countries). The results suggest that the centrality parameters are robust to the country specialisation for the top five exporting countries, while findings related to the whole sample show that the better a destination country is supplied, interconnected with influent exporters, and central for a specific exporter, the lower the export prices in that country.

Keywords

World trade system Export prices Network analysis Centrality 

References

  1. Anderson, J.E., van Wincoop, E.: Trade costs. J. Econ. Lit. 42, 691–751 (2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Baldwin, R.E., Harrigan, J.: Zeros, quality and space: trade theory and trade evidence. Am. Econ. J. Microecon. 3, 60–88 (2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Barigozzi, M., Fagiolo, G., Garlaschelli, D.: Multinetwork of international trade: a commodity specific analysis. Phys. Rev. E 81, 046104 (2010)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bastos, P., Silva, J.: The quality of a firm’s exports: where you export to matter. J. Int. Econ. 82(2), 99–111 (2010)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bonacich, P., Lloyd, P.: Eigenvector-like measures of centrality for asymmetric relations. Soc. Netw. 23(3), 191–201 (2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Brander, J., Krugman, P.: A ‘reciprocal dumping’ model of international trade. J. Int. Econ. 15(3–4), 313–321 (1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Chaney, T.: The gravity equation in international trade: an explanation. No. w19285, National Bureau of Economic Research (2013)Google Scholar
  8. De Benedictis, L., Nenci, S., Santoni, G., Tajoli, L., Vicarelli, C.: Network analysis of world trade using the BACI-CEPII dataset, CEPII WP No. 2013-24 (2013)Google Scholar
  9. De Denedictis, L., Tajoli, L.: Global and Local Centrality of Emerging Countries in the World Trade Network. Università di Macerata, Mimeo (2017)Google Scholar
  10. Deguchi, T., Takahashi, K., Takayasu, H., Takayasu, M.: Hubs and authorities in the world trade network using a weighted HITS algorithm. PLoS ONE 9(7), e100338 (2014)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Eaton, J., Kortum, S.: Technology, geography, and trade. Econometrica 70(5), 1741–1779 (2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Fagiolo, G., Reyes, J., Schiavo, S.: World-trade web: topological properties, dynamics, and evolution. Phys. Rev. E 79, 036115 (2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Fagiolo, G., Reyes, J., Schiavo, S.: The evolution of the world trade web: a weighted-network analysis. J. Evolut. Econ. 20, 479–514 (2010)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Freeman, L.C.: The development of social network analysis: a study in the sociology of science. BookSurge, North Charleston (2004)Google Scholar
  15. Garlaschelli, D., Di Matteo, T., Aste, T., Caldarelli, G., Loffredo, M.I.: Interplay between topology and dynamics in the World Trade Web. Eur. Phys. J. B 57, 159–164 (2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Garlaschelli, D., Loffredo, M.I.: Fitness-dependent topological properties of the world trade web. Phys. Rev. Lett. 93, 188701 (2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Garlaschelli, D., Loffredo, M.I.: Structure and evolution of the world trade network. Phys. A 355, 138–144 (2005a)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Garlaschelli, D., Loffredo, M.I.: Structure and evolution of the world trade network. Phys. A 355, 138–144 (2005b)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Gaulier, G., Zignago, S.: BACI: International trade database at the product-level. The 1994–2007 version, CEPII WP No. 2010-23 (2010)Google Scholar
  20. Harrigan, J., Ma, X., Shlychkov, V.: Export prices of U.S. firms, NBER Working Paper 17706 (2012)Google Scholar
  21. Hopenhayn, H.: Entry, exit, and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica 60, 621–653 (1992)Google Scholar
  22. Jackson, M.O.: Social and Economic Network. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2010)Google Scholar
  23. Kneller, R, Yu, Z.: Quality selection, chinese exports and theories of heterogeneous firm trade. http://www.etsg.org/ETSG2008/Papers/Kneller.pdf (2008)
  24. Kravis, I., Lipsey, R.: International trade prices and price proxies. In: Ruggles, N. (ed.) The Role of the Computer in Economic and Social Research in Latin America, pp. 253–266. Columbia University Press, New York (1974)Google Scholar
  25. Krugman, P.R., Obstfeld, M., Melitz, M.: International Economics, 9th edn. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River (2011)Google Scholar
  26. Krugman, P.: Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade. Am. Econ. Rev. 70(5), 950–959 (1980)Google Scholar
  27. Kugler, M., Verhoogen, E.: Prices, plant size and product quality. Rev. Econ. Stud. 79(1), 307–339 (2012)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Li, X., Jin, Y.Y., Chen, G.: Complexity and synchronization of the world trade web. Phys. A 328, 287–296 (2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Manova, K., Zhang, Z.: Export prices across firms and destinations. Q. J. Econ. 127, 379–436 (2012)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Martin, J.: Markups, quality, and transport costs. Eur. Econ. Rev. 56, 777–791 (2012)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Melitz, M.J.: The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6), 1695–1725 (2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Melitz, M.J., Ottaviano, G.I.P.: Market size, trade, and productivity. Rev. Econ. Stud. 75(1), 295–316 (2008)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Ottaviano, G., Tabuchi, T., Thisse, J.-F.: Agglomeration and trade revisited. Int. Econ. Rev. 43(2), 409–436 (2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Rauch, James E.: Networks versus markets in international trade. J. Int. Econ. 48(1), 7–35 (1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Serrano, M.A., Boguñá, M.: Topology of the world trade web. Phys. Rev. E 68, 015101 (2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Silver, M.: Do unit value export, import, and terms of trade indices represent or misrepresent price indices? IMF Working Paper 07/121 (2007)Google Scholar
  37. Squartini, T., Fagiolo, G., Garlaschelli, D.: Randomizing world trade. I. A binary network analysis. Phys. Rev. E 84, 046117 (2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Tinbergen, J.: Shaping the World Economy; Suggestions for an International Economic Policy. Books (Jan Tinbergen). Twentieth Century Fund, New York. Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/1765/16826 (1962)
  39. Trefler, D.: The case of the missing trade and other mysteries. Am. Econ. Rev. 1256, 1029–1046 (1995)Google Scholar
  40. Verhoogen, E.: Trade, quality upgrading and wage inequality in the mexican manufacturing sector. Q. J. Econ. 123(2), 489–530 (2008)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media B.V., part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Vittorio Carlei
    • 1
  • Francesca Affortunato
    • 1
  • Alessandro Marra
    • 1
  • Marco Brogi
    • 1
  1. 1.Universita degli Studi Gabriele d’Annunzio Chieti e PescaraPescaraItaly

Personalised recommendations