The rise and fall of family firms in the process of development
Abstract
This paper explores the causes and the consequences of the evolution of family firms in the growth process. The theory suggests that in early stages of development, valuable family specific human capital stimulated the productivity of family firms and the development process. However, in light of the rise in the importance of managerial talents for firms’ productivity in later stages, family firms generated a misallocation of managerial talents, curbing productivity and economic growth. Evidence supports the dual impact of family firms in the development process and the role of socio-cultural characteristics in observed variations in the productivity of family firms.
Keywords
Family firms Economic development and growth Culture and social structure Allocation of talents IndustrializationJEL Classification
D2 J62 L26 O14 O33 O4 Z1Notes
Acknowledgements
We are extremely grateful to Oded Galor (Editor-in-Chief) for the guidance and valuable comments that greatly improved this paper and to four anonymous referees for their suggestions. We warmly thank, for useful comments and suggestions, Francesco Drago, Stelios Michalopoulos, Holger Strulik and Fabrizio Zilibotti, as well as participants at the Conference on Intergenerational Transmission of Entrepreneurship, Occupations and Cultural Traits in the process of long-run economic growth (University of Naples Parthenope), Workshop on Economic Growth (OFCE-Nice), 2012 Annual Meeting of the Italian Economic Society (Matera), Workshop on Structural Change, Dynamics and Economic Growth (Livorno), NEUDC 2013 Conference (Harvard University), \(5^{th}\) Workshop on Equilibrium Analysis (University of Naples Federico II), 2014 Annual Conference of the Royal Economic Society (Manchester), 2014 Summer School in Economic Growth (Capri), 2014 Summer Workshop in Economic Growth (University of Warwick), 2015 Barcelona GSE Summer Forum (Barcelona), 2015 European Economic Association – Annual Meeting (Mannheim), 2017 13th CISEI (Capri), ASREC Europe 2017 (Bologna), and seminars held at Brown University, CSEF, Kobe University, Polytechnic University of Marche and University of Cagliari. Maria Rosaria Carillo and Vincenzo Lombardo gratefully acknowledge financial support from University of Naples Parthenope through the research funds programme “Bando di Ateneo per il sostegno alla partecipazione ai bandi di ricerca competitiva per il triennio 2016–2018”.
Supplementary material
References
- Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., & Zilibotti, F. (2006). Distance to frontier, selection and economic growth. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(1), 37–74.Google Scholar
- Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2010). The power of the family. Journal of Economic Growth, 15(2), 93–125.Google Scholar
- Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2014). Family ties. In Aghion, P., & Durlauf, S.N. (Eds.) Handbook of economic growth, vol 2, North Holland, chap 4, pp 177–215Google Scholar
- Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2015). Culture and institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 53(4), 898–944.Google Scholar
- Amore, M. D. (2016). Social capital and family control. Explorations in Economic History, 65, 106–114.Google Scholar
- Anderson, R. C., & Reeb, D. M. (2003). Founding-family ownership and firm performance: Evidence from the S&P 500. The Journal of Finance, 58(3), 1301–1328.Google Scholar
- Ashraf, Q., & Galor, O. (2011). Cultural diversity, geographical isolation, and the origin of the wealth of nations. Working Papers 2011-16, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
- Ashraf, Q., & Galor, O. (2013). The “Out of Africa” hypothesis, human genetic diversity, and comparative economic development. The American Economic Review, 103(1), 1–46.Google Scholar
- Ashraf, Q. H., & Galor, O. (2018). The macrogenoeconomics of comparative development. Journal of Economic Literature, 56(3), 1119–1155.Google Scholar
- Atack, J. (1986). Firm size and industrial structure in the United States during the nineteenth century. Journal of Economic History, 46(2), 463–475.Google Scholar
- Bennedsen, M., & Fan, J. P. (2014). The family business map. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
- Bennedsen, M., & Foss, N. (2015). Family assets and liabilities in the innovation process. California Management Review, 58(1), 65–81.Google Scholar
- Bentzen, J.S., Kaarsen, N., & Wingender, A.M. (2013). The timing of industrialization across countries. Dept. of economics discussion paper 13–17, University of Copenhagen.Google Scholar
- Bertrand, M., & Schoar, A. (2006). The role of family in family firms. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 88(2), 73–96.Google Scholar
- Bertrand, M., Johnson, S., Samphantharak, K., & Schoar, A. (2008). Mixing family with business: A study of Thai business groups and the families behind them. Journal of Financial Economics, 20(3), 466–498.Google Scholar
- Bhattacharya, U., & Ravikumar, B. (2001). Capital markets and the evolution of family businesses. The Journal of Business, 74(2), 187–219.Google Scholar
- Bloom, N., & Van Reenen, J. (2007). Measuring and explaining management practices across firms and countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(4), 1351–1408.Google Scholar
- Bloom, N., & Van Reenen, J. (2010). Why do management practices differ across firms and countries? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(1), 203–224.Google Scholar
- Bloom, N., Genakos, C., Sadun, R., & Van Reenen, J. (2012). Management practices across firms and countries. The Academy of Management Perspectives, 26(1), 12–33.Google Scholar
- Bloom, N., Sadun, R., & Van Reenen, J. (2016). Management as a technology? Working Paper 22327, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
- Buggle, J.C. (2017). Growing collectivism: Irrigation, group conformity and technological divergence, working paper.Google Scholar
- Bunkanwanicha, P., Fan, J. P., & Witwattanakantang, Y. (2013). The value of marriage to family firms. Review of Financial Studies, 48(2), 611–636.Google Scholar
- Burkart, M., Panunzi, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). Family firms. The Journal of Finance LVII, I(5), 2167–2201.Google Scholar
- Caselli, F., & Gennaioli, N. (2013). Dynastic management. Economic Inquiry, 51(1), 971–996.Google Scholar
- Chandler, A. D. J. (1977). The visible hand. The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
- Chandler, A. D. J. (1990). Scale and scope. The dynamics of industrial capitalism. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
- Chung, C. N., & Luo, X. R. (2013). Leadership succession and firm performance in an emerging economy: Successor origin, relational embeddedness, and legitimacy. Strategic Management Journal, 34, 338–357.Google Scholar
- Doepke, M., & Zilibotti, F. (2008). Occupational choice and the spirit of capitalism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 747–793.Google Scholar
- Doepke, M., & Zilibotti, F. (2014). Culture, entrepreneurship and growth. In Aghion, P., & Durlauf, S.N. (Eds.) Handbook of Economic growth, vol 2, North Holland, chap 1, pp 1–48.Google Scholar
- Ellul, A., Pagano, M., & Panunzi, F. (2010). Inheritance law and investment in family firms. The American Economic Review, 100(5), 2414–2450.Google Scholar
- Fisman, R. (2001). Estimating the value of political connections. The American Economic Review, 91(4), 1095–1102.Google Scholar
- Fogli, A., & Veldkamp, L. (2018). Germs, social networks and growth. Staff Report 572, Federal reserve bank of Minneapolis, Research Division.Google Scholar
- Galor, O., & Michalopoulos, S. (2012). Evolution and the growth process: Natural selection of entrepreneurial traits. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(2), 759–780.Google Scholar
- Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2000). Ability-biased technological transition, wage inequality, and economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2), 469–497.Google Scholar
- Giuliano, P., & Nunn, N. (2017). Understanding cultural persistence and change. Working paper 23617, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
- Gollin, D. (2008). Nobody’s business but my own: Self-employment and small enterprise in economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55, 219–233.Google Scholar
- Gorodnichenko, Y., & Roland, G. (2011). Individualism, innovation, and long-run growth. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(Supplement 4), 21316–21319.Google Scholar
- Gorodnichenko, Y., & Roland, G. (2017). Culture, institutions and the wealth of nations. Review of Economics and Statistics, 99(3), 402–416.Google Scholar
- Hassler, J., & Mora, J. V. R. (2000). Intelligence, social mobility, and growth. The American Economic Review, 90(4), 888–908.Google Scholar
- Hémous, D., & Olsen, M. (2017). Long-term relationships: Static gains and dynamic inefficiencies. Journal of the European Economic Association, 16(2), 383–435.Google Scholar
- Hofstede, G., Hofstede, G. J., & Minkov, M. (2010). Cultures and organizations: Software of the mind (3rd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
- van Hoorn, A. (2014). Individualism and the cultural roots of management practices. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 99, 53–68.Google Scholar
- Iyigun, M. F., & Owen, A. L. (1999). Entrepreneurs, professionals, and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 4, 213–232.Google Scholar
- Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The worldwide governance indicators: A summary of methodology, data and analytical issues. Working paper 5430, World Bank Policy Research.Google Scholar
- La Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 471–517.Google Scholar
- Lindquist, M. J., Sol, J., & Van Praag, M. (2015). Why do entrepreneurial parents have entrepreneurial children? Journal of Labor Economics, 33(2), 269–296.Google Scholar
- Lucas, R. E. J. (1978). On the size distribution of business firms. The Bell Journal of Economics, 9(2), 508–523.Google Scholar
- Mehrotra, V., Morck, R., Shim, J., & Wiwattanakantang, Y. (2013). Adoptive expectations: Rising sons in Japanese family firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 108(3), 840–854.Google Scholar
- Morck, R. K., & Yeung, B. (2003). Family firms and the rent seeking society. Entrepreneurship, Theory & Practice, 28(3), 391–409.Google Scholar
- Mueller, H. M., & Philippon, T. (2011). Family firms and labor relations. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3(1), 218–245.Google Scholar
- Olsson, O., & Paik, C. (2016). Long-run cultural divergence: Evidence from the neolithic revolution. Journal of Development Economics, 122, 197–213.Google Scholar
- Pérez-González, F. (2006). Inherited control and firm performance. The American Economic Review, 96(5), 1559–1588.Google Scholar
- Pollak, R. A. (1980). A transaction cost approach to families and households. Journal of Economic Literature, 23(2), 581–608.Google Scholar
- Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (1998). Financial dependence and growth. The American Economic Review, 88(3), 559–586.Google Scholar
- Sraer, D., & Thesmar, D. (2007). Performance and behavior of family firms: Evidence from the French stock market. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(4), 709–751.Google Scholar
- Tabellini, G. (2008). Presidential address: Institutions and culture. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(2–3), 255–294.Google Scholar
- Tabellini, G. (2010). Culture and institutions: Economic development in the regions of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(4), 677–716.Google Scholar
- Terviö, M. (2008). The difference that CEOs make: An assignment model approach. The American Economic Review, 98(3), 642–668.Google Scholar
- Villalonga, B., & Amit, R. (2006). How do family ownership, control and management affect firm value? Journal of Fianancial Economics, 80, 385–417.Google Scholar
- Xu, N., Yuan, Q., Jiang, X., & Chan, K. C. (2015). Founder’s political connections, second generation involvement, and family firm performance: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 33(August), 243–259.Google Scholar