Advertisement

Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade

, Volume 19, Issue 4, pp 561–581 | Cite as

Impact of Vertical Integration on Market Power in Indian Manufacturing Sector During the Post-Reform Period

  • Rakesh BasantEmail author
  • Pulak Mishra
Article
  • 99 Downloads

Abstract

In the context of declining degrees of vertical integration in major industries of Indian manufacturing sector during the post-reform period, the present paper is an attempt to examine how such “vertical disintegration” has affected firms’ market power and its implications for competition policy. Using panel dataset of 49 majors industries of Indian manufacturing sector for the period 2003–04 to 2010–11 and applying the system generalized method of moments approach to estimate of dynamic panel data models, the paper finds that vertical integration does not cause any significant impact on average market power of firms in an industry. Instead, it is influenced by market size, and selling and technology-related efforts. While selling intensity has a positive impact on market power, the impact of market size and technology intensity is found to be negative. Notably, like vertical integration, market concentration, import to export ratio, and capital intensity also do not have any significant impact on market power. The findings of this paper, therefore, have important implications for competition law and policy in general and policies and regulation relating to technology development and international trade in particular.

Keywords

Economic reforms Vertical integration Market power Competition policy India 

JEL Classification

D4 L1 L2 L5 

Notes

References

  1. Adelman MA (1955) Concept and statistical measure of vertical integration. In: NBER (ed) Business Concentration and Price Policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 281–330Google Scholar
  2. Ahn SC, Schmidt P (1995) Efficient estimation of models for dynamic panel data. J Econ 68(1):5–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Anderson TW, Hsiao C (1982) Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data. J Econ 18(1):47–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58(2):277–297Google Scholar
  5. Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at instrumental variables estimation of error component models. J Econ 68(1):29–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Aschhoff B, Schmidt T (2008) Empirical evidence on the success of R&D cooperation—happy together? Rev Ind Organ 33(1):41–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Asker J (2004) Diagnosing foreclosure due to exclusive dealing, Working Paper 04–36, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, Department of Economics, New York UniversityGoogle Scholar
  8. Bain JS (1951) Relation of profit rate to industrial concentration: American manufacturing, 1936-1940. Q J Econ 65(3):293–324CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Bain JS (1956) Barriers to new competition: their character and consequences in manufacturing industries. Harvard University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Balcer Y, Lippman SA (1984) Technological expectations and adoption of improved technology. J Econ Theory 34(2):292–318CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Balestra P, Nerlove M (1966) Pooling cross section and time-series data in the estimation of a dynamic model: the demand for natural gas. Econometrica 34(3):585–612CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Basant R, Mishra P (2016) Trends in strategies and performance of the Indian corporate sector what has changed in two decades of economic reforms?, working paper no 2016-03-31. Indian Institute of Management, AhmedabadGoogle Scholar
  13. Basant R, Saha SN (2005) Determinants of entry in the Indian manufacturing sector, working paper no 2005-01-01. Indian Institute of Management, AhmedabadGoogle Scholar
  14. Baumol WJ, Penzar JC, Willig RD (1982) Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, San DiegoGoogle Scholar
  15. Bhandari A (2010) Concentration, entry barriers and profitability in the Indian industries: an empirical analysis. J Quant Econ 8(2):61–80Google Scholar
  16. Bhargava A, Sargan J (1983) Estimating dynamic random effects models from panel data covering short periods. Econometrica 51(6):1635–1660CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Bhattacharya M (2002) Industrial concentration and competition in Malaysian manufacturing. Appl Econ 34(17):2127–2134CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Bhuyan S (2005) Does vertical integration effect market power? Evidence from U. S. Food manufacturing industries. J Agric Appl Econ 37(1):263–276CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econ 87(1):115–143CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Branstetter LG (2004) Do stronger patents induce more local innovation? J Int Econ Law 7(2):359–370CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Carlton DW (1979) Vertical Integration in Competitive Markets under Uncertainty, J Ind Econ 27(3):189–209Google Scholar
  22. Carlton DW, Perloff J (2005) Modern industrial organization, 4th edn. Pearson Addison Wesley, BostonGoogle Scholar
  23. Cefis E (1998) Persistence in profitability and in innovative activities, Working Paper. Bocconi University and University of BerganoGoogle Scholar
  24. Chamberlin EH (1933) The theory of monopolistic competition. Harvard University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  25. Chatterjee S (1986) Types of synergy and economic value: the impact of acquisitions on merging and rival firms. Strateg Manag J 7(2):119–139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Chipty T (2001) Vertical integration, market foreclosure, and consumer welfare in the cable television industry. Am Econ Rev 91(3):428–453CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Choi I (2001) Unit root tests for panel data. J Int Money Financ 20(2):249–272CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Clemens MA, Radelet S, Bhavnani RR, Bazzi S (2012) Counting chickens when they hatch: timing and the effects of aid on growth. Econ J 122:590–617CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4(16):386–405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Comanor WS, Wilson TA (1967) Advertising, market structure and performance. Rev Econ Stat 49(4):423–440CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Comanor WS and Wilson TA (1974) Advertising and Market Power, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
  32. Das BJ, Chappell WF, Shughartii WF (1993) Advertising, competition and market share instability. Appl Econ 25(11):1409–1412CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Delorme CD, Klein PG, Kamerschen DR, Voeks LF (2002) Structure conduct and performance: a simultaneous equations approach. Appl Econ 35(17):13–20Google Scholar
  34. Domowitz I, Hubbard RG, Petersen BC (1986) Business cycles and the relationship between concentration and price-cost margins. RAND J Econ 17(1):1–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Ghose A (1975) Concentration and controls in the Indian industry. J Ind Econ 23(3):203–222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Ginevicius R, Cibra S (2009) Additive measurement of market concentration. J Bus Econ Manag 10(3):191–198CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Goldar B, Aggarwal SC (2004) Trade Liberalization and Price-Cost Margin in Indian Industries, Working Paper No. 130. Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations, New DelhiGoogle Scholar
  38. Gort M (1962) Diversification and Integration in American Industry, Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
  39. Grossman S, Hart O (1986) The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration. J Polit Econ 94(4):691–719CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Gupta N (2005) Partial privatization and firm performance. J Financ 60(2):987–1015CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Hart O (1995) Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford University Press, Clarendon Press, Oxford and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  42. Hart O, Moore J (1990) Property rights and the nature of the firm. J Polit Econ 98(6):1119–1158CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Hastings JS (2004) Vertical relationships and competition in retail gasoline markets: empirical evidence from contract changes in Southern California. Am Econ Rev 94(1):317–328CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Hastings JS, Gilbert RJ (2005) Market power, vertical integration and the wholesale price of gasoline. J Ind Econ 53(4):469–492CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Hay D, Morris D (1991) Industrial economics and organization. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  46. Hendricks K, McAfee RP (2000) A theory of bilateral oligopoly, with applications to vertical mergers. Mimeo, Department of Economics, University of Texas at AustinGoogle Scholar
  47. Hinomoto H (1965) Capacity expansion with facilities under technological improvement. Manag Sci 11(5):581–592CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Hortac ̧su A, Syverson C (2007) Cementing relationships: vertical integration, foreclosure, productivity, and prices. J Polit Econ 115(2):250–301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Kambhampati US (1996) Industrial concentration and performance; a study of the structure, conduct and performance of Indian industry. Oxford University Press, DelhiGoogle Scholar
  50. Kambhampati US, Parikh A (2005) Has liberalization affected profit margins in Indian industry? Bull Econ Res 57(3):273–304CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Katrak H (1980) Industry structure, foreign trade and price-cost margins in Indian manufacturing industries. J Dev Stud 17(1):62–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Koch JV (1980) Industrial organization and prices. Prentice Hall, Englewood CliffsGoogle Scholar
  53. Kuhn KU, Wives X (1999) Excess entry, vertical integration, and welfare. RAND J Econ 30(4):575–603CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Laffer AB (1969) Vertical Integration by Corporations, 1929-1965 The Review of Economics and Statistics, 51(1):91–93Google Scholar
  55. Liebowitz SJ (1982) What do census price-cost margins measure? J Law Econ 25(2):231–246CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Majumdar S (1997) The impact of size and age on firm-level performance: some evidence from India. Rev Ind Organ 12(2):231–241CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Martin S (1979) Advertising, concentration, and profitability: the simultaneity problem. Bell J Econ 10(2):639–647CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Martin S (1988) Market power and/or efficiency? Rev Econ Stat 70(2):331–335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Martin S (1993) Advanced Industrial Economics, Oxford: Blackwell PublishersGoogle Scholar
  60. Martin S (1994) Industrial economics: economic analysis and public policy. Prentice Hall, Englewood CliffsGoogle Scholar
  61. McAfee RP (1999) The effects of vertical integration on competing input suppliers. Fed Reserv Bank Cleve Econ Rev 35(1):2–8Google Scholar
  62. McDonald JT (1999) The determinants of firm profitability in Australian manufacturing. Econ Rec 75(2):115–126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Mishra P (2008) Concentration-markup relationship in Indian manufacturing sector. Econ Polit Wkly 43(39):74–81Google Scholar
  64. Mishra P, Chandra T (2010) Mergers, acquisitions and firms’ performance: experience of Indian pharmaceutical industry. Eurasian J Bus Econ 3(5):111–126Google Scholar
  65. Mishra P, Vikas (2010) Structure, conduct and performance in Indian pharmaceutical industry, a simultaneous equations investigation. Rev Dev Chang 15(1):69–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Mishra P, Mohit D, Parimal (2011) Market concentration in Indian manufacturing sector: measurement issues. Econ Polit Wkly 46(49):76–80Google Scholar
  67. Mishra P, and Rao US (2014) Concentration vs. Inequality Measures of Market Structure: An Exploration of Indian Manufacturing, Economic and Political Weekly 49(33):59–65Google Scholar
  68. Mueller DC (1990) The dynamics of company profits, an international comparison. Cambridge University Press, New YorkCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Nelson RL (1963) Concentration in the Manufacturing Industries of the United States, New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
  70. Newey WK, West KD (1994) Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. Rev Econ Stud 61(4):631–653CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Nocke V, White L (2007) Do vertical mergers facilitate upstream collusion? Am Econ Rev 97(4):1321–1339CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Normann HT (2009) Vertical integration, raising rival’s costs and upstream collusion. Eur Econ Rev 53(4):461–480CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Nugent EJ, Hamblin DJ (1996) Improved methodologies for vertical integration research. Integr Manuf Syst 7(1):16–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Ordover JA, Saloner G, Salop SC (1990) Equilibrium vertical foreclosure. Am Econ Rev 80(1):127–142Google Scholar
  75. Ornstein SI (1975) Empirical uses of the price-cost margin. J Ind Econ 24(2):105–117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Panchamukhi VR (1974) A Quantitative analysis of trade policies in India. In: Sandesara JC (ed) The Indian Economy: Performance and Prospects. University of Bombay, BombayGoogle Scholar
  77. Perry M (1989) Vertical integration: determinants and effects. In: Schmalensee R, Willig R (eds) Handbook of Industrial Organization I. ElsevierGoogle Scholar
  78. Perry MK (1978) Price discrimination and forward integration. Bell J Econ 9(1):209Google Scholar
  79. Porter ME (1985) The competitive advantage. The Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  80. Quirmbach H (1986) The path of price changes in vertical integration. J Polit Econ 94(5):1100–1109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Rao PA (2001) A study of the determinants of firm profitability in selected industries in post-reform India, Unpublished M. Phil. Dissertation, Delhi School of Economics, University of DelhiGoogle Scholar
  82. Ravenscraft DJ (1983) Structure-profit relationships at the line of business and industry level. Rev Econ Stat 65(1):22–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. Riordan MH (1998) Anticompetitive vertical integration by a dominant firm. Am Econ Rev 88:1232–1248Google Scholar
  84. Riordan MH (2005) Competitive effects of vertical integration, Discussion Paper No.: 0506–11, Department of Economic, Columbia UniversityGoogle Scholar
  85. Riordan MH, Salop SC (1995) Evaluating vertical mergers: a post-Chicago approach. Antitrust Law J 63(2):513–568Google Scholar
  86. Roodman D (2006) How to do xtabond2: an Introduction to “Difference” and “System” GMM in Stata, Working Paper No. 103. Center for Global Development, Washington DCGoogle Scholar
  87. Rosengren ES, James WM Jr (1994) Empirical evidence on vertical foreclosure. Econ Inq 32(2):303–317CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. Salinger M (1988) Vertical mergers and market foreclosure. Q J Econ 103(2):345–356CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Salinger M, Caves RE, Peltzman S (1990) The concentration-margins relationship reconsidered. In: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, pp 287–335Google Scholar
  90. Saluja MR (1968) Structure of Indian economy: inter-industry flows and pattern of final demands 1964-65. Sankhya Ser B 30(1/2):97–122Google Scholar
  91. Sargan JD (1958) The estimation of economic relationships using instrumental variables. Econometrica 26(3):393–415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Scherer FM, Ross D (1990) Industrial market structure and economic performance. Rand Mcnally, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  93. Shelton LM (1988) Strategic business fits and corporate acquisitions: empirical evidence. Strateg Manag J 9(3):279–287CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. Shepherd WG (1982) Causes of industrial competition in the U. S. Economy, 1939-1980. Rev Econ Stat 64(4):613–626CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  95. Shepherd WG, Shepherd JM (2004) The economics of industrial organization, 5th edn. Waveland Press, Inc., Long GroveGoogle Scholar
  96. Steiner PO (1975) Mergers, Motives, Effects and Policies, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
  97. Stigler G (1951) The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. J Polit Econ 59(3):185–193CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  98. Stigler GJ (1964) A theory of oligopoly. J Polit Econ 72(1):44–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  99. Suzuki A (2008) Market foreclosure and vertical merger: a case study of the vertical merger between turner broadcasting and Time Warner. Int J Ind Organ 27(4):532–543CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  100. Tirole J (1988) The theory of industrial organization, MIT PressGoogle Scholar
  101. Tucker IB and Wilder RP (1977) Trends in Vertical Integration in the U.S. Manufacturing Sector, Journal of Ind Econ 26(1):81–94Google Scholar
  102. Weiss LW (1974) The concentration-profits relationship and antitrust. In: Goldschmid HJ, Michael Mann H, Fred Weston J (eds) Industrial concentration, the new learning. Little Brown, BostonGoogle Scholar
  103. Williamson OE (1971) The vertical integration of production: market failure considerations. Am Econ Rev 61(2):112–123Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Economics, Indian Institute of Management AhmedabadAhmedabadIndia
  2. 2.Department of Humanities and Social SciencesIndian Institute of Technology KharagpurKharagpurIndia

Personalised recommendations