Advertisement

Experimental Economics

, Volume 22, Issue 1, pp 24–50 | Cite as

Is fairness intuitive? An experiment accounting for subjective utility differences under time pressure

  • Anna Louisa MerkelEmail author
  • Johannes Lohse
Original Paper

Abstract

Evidence from response time studies and time pressure experiments has led several authors to conclude that “fairness is intuitive”. In light of conflicting findings, we provide theoretical arguments showing under which conditions an increase in “fairness” due to time pressure indeed provides unambiguous evidence in favor of the “fairness is intuitive” hypothesis. Drawing on recent applications of the Drift Diffusion Model (Krajbich et al. in Nat Commun 6:7455, 2015a), we demonstrate how the subjective difficulty of making a choice affects decisions under time pressure and time delay, thereby making an unambiguous interpretation of time pressure effects contingent on the choice situation. To explore our theoretical considerations and to retest the “fairness is intuitive” hypothesis, we analyze choices in two-person binary dictator and prisoner’s dilemma games under time pressure or time delay. In addition, we manipulate the subjective difficulty of choosing the fair relative to the selfish option. Our main finding is that time pressure does not consistently promote fairness in situations where this would be predicted after accounting for choice difficulty. Hence, our results cast doubt on the hypothesis that “fairness is intuitive”.

Keywords

Distributional preferences Cooperation Time pressure Response times Cognitive processes Drift Diffusion Models 

JEL Classification

C32 C72 C91 D64 D91 H41 

Notes

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Christoph Vanberg, Gustav Tinghög, Ariel Rubinstein, Ernst Fehr, Tobias Pfrommer, Daniel Heyen, Gert Pönitzsch, as well as seminar participants at the University of Heidelberg, ZEW Mannheim, IfW Kiel, Thurgau Experimental Economics Meeting, IMEBESS Rome, Kings College London and ESA Bergen for their helpful comments. In addition, we would like to thank the editors as well as two anonymous referees for their tremendously helpful feedback on an earlier version of this paper. 

Supplementary material

10683_2018_9566_MOESM1_ESM.pdf (874 kb)
Supplementary material 1 (pdf 874 KB)

References

  1. Achtziger, A., Alós-Ferrer, C., & Wagner, A. K. (2015). Money, depletion, and prosociality in the dictator game. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics, 8(1), 1.Google Scholar
  2. Alós-Ferrer, C. (2016). A dual-process diffusion model. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making,.  https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.1960.Google Scholar
  3. Alós-Ferrer, C., & Strack, F. (2014). From dual processes to multiple selves: Implications for economic behavior. Journal of Economic Psychology, 41, 1–11.Google Scholar
  4. Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to garp: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737–753.Google Scholar
  5. Bear, A., & Rand, D. G. (2016). Intuition, deliberation, and the evolution of cooperation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 113(4), 936–941.Google Scholar
  6. Bock, O., Baetge, I., & Nicklisch, A. (2014). hroot: Hamburg registration and organization online tool. European Economic Review, 71, 117–120.Google Scholar
  7. Bogacz, R., Brown, E., Moehlis, J., Holmes, P., & Cohen, J. D. (2006). The physics of optimal decision making: A formal analysis of models of performance in two-alternative forced-choice tasks. Psychological Review, 113(4), 700.Google Scholar
  8. Bouwmeester, S., Verkoeijen, P. P., Aczel, B., Barbosa, F., Bègue, L., Brañas-Garza, P., et al. (2017). Registered replication report: Rand, greene, and nowak (2012). Perspectives on Psychological Science, 12(3), 527–542.Google Scholar
  9. Buckert, M., Oechssler, J., & Schwieren, C. (2017). Imitation under stress. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 139, 252–266.Google Scholar
  10. Caplin, A., & Martin, D. (2015). The dual-process drift diffusion model: Evidence from response times. Economic Inquiry, 54(2), 1274–1282.Google Scholar
  11. Cappelen, A. W., Nielsen, U. H., Tungodden, B., Tyran, J.-R., & Wengström, E. (2016). Fairness is intuitive. Experimental Economics, 19, 727–740.Google Scholar
  12. Capraro, V., & Cococcioni, G. (2016). Rethinking spontaneous giving: Extreme time pressure and ego-depletion favor self-regarding reactions. Scientific Reports, 6, 27219.Google Scholar
  13. Capraro, V., Corgnet, B., Espín, A. M., & Hernán-González, R. (2017). Deliberation favours social efficiency by making people disregard their relative shares: Evidence from USA and India. Royal Society Open Science, 4(2), 160605.Google Scholar
  14. Chen, F., & Fischbacher, U. (2015). Cognitive processes of distributional preferences: A response time study. Research Paper Series Thurgauer Wirtschaftsinstitut.Google Scholar
  15. Clithero, J. A. (2016). Response times in economics: Looking through the lens of sequential sampling models. Available at SSRN.  https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2795871.
  16. Cubitt, R. P., Drouvelis, M., Gächter, S., & Kabalin, R. (2011). Moral judgments in social dilemmas: How bad is free riding? Journal of Public Economics, 95(3), 253–264.Google Scholar
  17. Dreber, A., Fudenberg, D., Levine, D. K., & Rand, D. G. (2014). Self-control, social preferences and the effect of delayed payments. Available at SSRN.  https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1752366.
  18. Drouvelis, M., & Grosskopf, B. (2016). The effects of induced emotions on pro-social behaviour. Journal of Public Economics, 134, 1–8.Google Scholar
  19. Duffy, S., & Smith, J. (2014). Cognitive load in the multi-player prisoner’s dilemma game: Are there brains in games? Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 51, 47–56.Google Scholar
  20. Engelmann, D., & Strobel, M. (2004). Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple distribution experiments. The American Economic Review, 94(4), 857–869.Google Scholar
  21. Faravelli, M. (2007). How context matters: A survey based experiment on distributive justice. Journal of Public Economics, 91(7), 1399–1422.Google Scholar
  22. Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (2006). The economics of fairness, reciprocity and altruism experimental evidence and new theories. Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, 1, 615–691.Google Scholar
  23. Fiedler, S., Glöckner, A., Nicklisch, A., & Dickert, S. (2013). Social value orientation and information search in social dilemmas: An eye-tracking analysis. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 120(2), 272–284.Google Scholar
  24. Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.Google Scholar
  25. Frederick, S. (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 25–42.Google Scholar
  26. Goeschl, T., & Lohse, J. (2016). Cooperation in public good games. Calculated or confused? AWI Discussion Paper Series No 626.Google Scholar
  27. Hawkins, G. E., Forstmann, B. U., Wagenmakers, E.-J., Ratcliff, R., & Brown, S. D. (2015). Revisiting the evidence for collapsing boundaries and urgency signals in perceptual decision-making. Journal of Neuroscience, 35(6), 2476–2484.Google Scholar
  28. Hieber, P., & Scherer, M. (2012). A note on first-passage times of continuously time-changed brownian motion. Statistics & Probability Letters, 82(1), 165–172.Google Scholar
  29. Hopfensitz, A., & Reuben, E. (2009). The Importance of Emotions for the Effectiveness of Social Punishment. The Economic Journal, 119(540), 1534–1559.Google Scholar
  30. Jagau, S., & van Veelen, M. (2017). A general evolutionary framework for the role of intuition and deliberation in cooperation. Nature Human Behavior, 1, 0152.Google Scholar
  31. Kahneman, D. (2003). A perspective on judgment and choice: Mapping bounded rationality. American Psychologist, 58(9), 697.Google Scholar
  32. Kocher, M. G., Martinsson, P., Myrseth, K. O. R., & Wollbrant, C. E. (2016). Strong, bold, and kind: Self-control and cooperation in social dilemmas. Experimental Economics, 20(1), 44–69.Google Scholar
  33. Krajbich, I., Bartling, B., Hare, T., & Fehr, E. (2015a). Rethinking fast and slow based on a critique of reaction-time reverse inference. Nature Communications, 6, 7455.Google Scholar
  34. Krajbich, I., Hare, T., Bartling, B., Morishima, Y., & Fehr, E. (2015b). A common mechanism underlying food choice and social decisions. PLoS Computational Biology, 11(10), e1004371.Google Scholar
  35. Krajbich, I., Oud, B., & Fehr, E. (2014). Benefits of neuroeconomic modeling: New policy interventions and predictors of preference. The American Economic Review, 104(5), 501–506.Google Scholar
  36. Ledyard, J. (Unpublished). Public goods: A survey of experimental research. Social Science Working Paper, 861. California Institute of Technology, Pasadena, CA.Google Scholar
  37. Loewenstein, G. (2000). Emotions in economic theory and economic behavior. The American Economic Review, 90(2), 426–432.Google Scholar
  38. Lohse, J. (2016). Smart or selfish—When smart guys finish nice. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 64(10), 28–40.Google Scholar
  39. Martinsson, P., Myrseth, K. O. R., & Wollbrant, C. (2014). Social dilemmas: When self-control benefits cooperation. Journal of Economic Psychology, 45, 213–236.Google Scholar
  40. Milosavljevic, M., Malmaud, J., Huth, A., Koch, C., & Rangel, A. (2010). The drift diffusion model can account for value-based choice response times under high and low time pressure. Judgment and Decision Making, 5(6), 437–449.Google Scholar
  41. Mischkowski, D., & Glöckner, A. (2016). Spontaneous cooperation for prosocials, but not for proselfs: Social value orientation moderates spontaneous cooperation behavior. Scientific Reports, 6, 21555.Google Scholar
  42. Mrkva, K. (2017). Giving, fast and slow: Reflection increases costly (but not uncostly) charitable giving. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 30(5), 1052–1065.Google Scholar
  43. Myrseth, K. O. R., & Wollbrant, C. E. (2016). Models inconsistent with altruism cannot explain the evolution of human cooperation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 113(18), E2472.Google Scholar
  44. Myrseth, K. O. R., & Wollbrant, C. E. (2017). Cognitive foundations of cooperation revisited: Commentary on rand et al. (2012, 2014). Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 69, 133–138.Google Scholar
  45. Nishi, A., Christakis, N. A., & Rand, D. G. (2017). Cooperation, decision time, and culture: Online experiments with american and indian participants. PLoS ONE, 12(2), e0171252.Google Scholar
  46. Palmer, J., Huk, A. C., & Shadlen, M. N. (2005). The effect of stimulus strength on the speed and accuracy of a perceptual decision. Journal of Vision, 5(5), 1–1.Google Scholar
  47. Polanía, R., Krajbich, I., Grueschow, M., & Ruff, C. C. (2014). Neural oscillations and synchronization differentially support evidence accumulation in perceptual and value-based decision making. Neuron, 82(3), 709–720.Google Scholar
  48. Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. The American Economic Review, 83(5), 1281–1302.Google Scholar
  49. Rand, D. G., Brescoll, V. L., Everett, J. A., Capraro, V., & Barcelo, H. (2016). Social heuristics and social roles: Intuition favors altruism for women but not for men. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 145(4), 389.Google Scholar
  50. Rand, D. G., Greene, J. D., & Nowak, M. A. (2012). Spontaneous giving and calculated greed. Nature, 489(7416), 427–430.Google Scholar
  51. Rand, D. G., Peysakhovich, A., Kraft-Todd, G. T., Newman, G. E., Wurzbacher, O., Nowak, M. A., et al. (2014). Social heuristics shape intuitive cooperation. Nature Communications, 5, 3677.Google Scholar
  52. Ratcliff, R. (1988). Continuous versus discrete information processing: Modeling accumulation of partial information. American Psychological Association, 95(2), 238–255.Google Scholar
  53. Ratcliff, R., & Rouder, J. N. (1998). Modeling response times for two-choice decisions. Psychological Science, 9(5), 347–356.Google Scholar
  54. Recalde, M. P., Riedl, A., & Vesterlund, L. (2014). Error prone inference from response time: The case of intuitive generosity. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 4987.Google Scholar
  55. Reuben, E., & Riedl, A. (2013). Enforcement of contribution norms in public good games with heterogeneous populations. Games and Economic Behavior, 77(1), 122–137.Google Scholar
  56. Rubinstein, A. (2007). Instinctive and cognitive reasoning: A study of response times. The Economic Journal, 117(523), 1243–1259.Google Scholar
  57. Smith, P. L. (2000). Stochastic dynamic models of response time and accuracy: A foundational primer. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 44(3), 408–463.Google Scholar
  58. Spiliopoulos, L., & Ortmann, A. (2017). The BCD of response time analysis in experimental economics. Experimental Economics.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9528-1.Google Scholar
  59. Stromland, E., Tjotta, S., & Torsvik, G. (2016). Cooperating, fast and slow: Testing the social heuristics hypothesis. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 5875.Google Scholar
  60. Tinghög, G., Andersson, D., Bonn, C., Böttiger, H., Josephson, C., Lundgren, G., et al. (2013). Intuition and cooperation reconsidered. Nature, 498(7452), 427–430.Google Scholar
  61. Tinghög, G., Andersson, D., Bonn, C., Johannesson, M., Kirchler, M., Koppel, L., et al. (2016). Intuition and moral decision-making-the effect of time pressure and cognitive load on moral judgment and altruistic behavior. PLoS ONE, 11(10), e0164012.Google Scholar
  62. Verkoeijen, P. P., & Bouwmeester, S. (2014). Does intuition cause cooperation? PLoS ONE, 9(5), e96654.Google Scholar
  63. Voss, A., Rothermund, K., & Voss, J. (2004). Interpreting the parameters of the diffusion model: An empirical validation. Memory & Cognition, 32(7), 1206–1220.Google Scholar
  64. Wright, P. (1974). The harassed decision maker: Time pressures, distractions, and the use of evidence. Journal of Applied Psychology, 59(5), 555–561.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Economic Science Association 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of HeidelbergHeidelbergGermany
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsUniversity of BirminghamBirminghamUK

Personalised recommendations