Microeconomic models of a production economy with environmental externalities
- 17 Downloads
Abstract
The environmental issue has surely become a central theme in the economic debate. From one side, this is analysed through large empirical models, solved numerically, that describe explicitly production and consumption\utility functions. On the other side, when environmental problems have a multinational dimension or, simply, involve a multiplicity of stakeholders, the game theoretical approach, focused on the strategic dimension of this problem, offers analytic solutions based on simple utility functions having only pollution and\or abatement as arguments. Although there are examples of large-scale empirical models taking into account game theoretical insights, the diversity in representing the same problem constitutes a gap for these two economic approaches to find a better integration. The present paper tries to bridge the mentioned gap by offering a family of models enough simple to be solved analytically, but where production and consumption, together with environmental aspects, are explicitly portrayed. Although the paper does not tackle directly the game theoretical aspect, the aim of the proposed family of models is to be used in game theoretical analysis in order to improve their representation of the economic–environmental linkage. Furthermore, in the proposed models, the negative consequences of pollution are divided into their detrimental effect on production activities and on utility. This last aspect is modelled in a novel way through the direct introduction into the utility function of an hypothetical environmental good whose consumption’s possibilities are diminished by pollution.
Keywords
Environmental externalities Microeconomic models Optimal taxation UtilityJEL Classification
D51 D62Notes
References
- Antimiani, A., Costantini, V., Martini, C., Palma, A., & Tommasino, M. C. (2012). The GTAP-E: Model description and improvements. In V. Costantini & M. Mazzanti (Eds.), The dynamics of environmental and economic systems (pp. 3–24). Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Argenziano, R., & Gilboa, I. (2017). Psychophysical foundations of the Cobb–Douglas utility function. Economics Letters, 157, 21–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Barrett, S. (1994). Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxford Economic Papers, 46, 878–894.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Baumol, W. J. (1972). On taxation and the control of externalities. The American Economic Review, 62, 307–322.Google Scholar
- Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., Galeotti, M., Massetti, E., & Tavoni, M. (2006). WITCH a world induced technical change hybrid model. The Energy Journal, 27(Special Issue: Hybrid Modeling of Energy-Environment Policies: Reconciling Bottom-up and Top-down 2006), 13–37.Google Scholar
- Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., De Cian, E., Duval, R., Massetti, E., & Tavoni, M. (2009). The incentives to participate in and the stability of international climate coalitions: A game theoretic approach using the witch model. Venice: International Center for Climate Governance.Google Scholar
- Buchanan, J. M., & Craig Stubblebine, W. (1962). Externality. Economica, 29(116), 371–384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Burfisher, M. E. (2011). Introduction to computable general equilibrium models. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chander, P., & Tulkens, H. (2006). The core of an economy with multilateral environmental externalities. In P. Chander, J. Drèze, C. K. Lovell, & J. Mintz (Eds.), Public goods, environmental externalities and fiscal competition (pp. 153–175). Boston: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- d’Aspremont, C., Jacquemin, A., Gabszewicz, J. J., & Weymark, J. A. (1983). On the stability of collusive price leadership. Canadian Journal of economics, 16, 17–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- De Young, R. (1999). Tragedy of the commons. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
- Dellink, R. (2011). Drivers of stability of climate coalitions in the STACO model. Climate Change Economics, 2(02), 105–128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dellink, R. B., Nagashima, M., van Ierland, E. C., Hendrix, E., Sáiz, E., & Weikard, H.-P. (2009). STACO technical document 2: Model description and calibration of STACO-2.1. Mansholt Graduate School Discussion Paper, 49.Google Scholar
- Diamantoudi, E., & Sartzetakis, E. S. (2006). Stable international environmental agreements: An analytical approach. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 8(2), 247–263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Diamantoudi, E., & Sartzetakis, E. S. (2015). International environmental agreements: Coordinated action under foresight. Economic Theory, 59(3), 527–546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dorfman, R., & Dorfman, N. S. (1972). Economics of the environment: Selected readings. New York: WW Norton.Google Scholar
- Easter, R. C., Ghan, S. J., Zhang, Y., Saylor, R. D., Chapman, E. G., Laulainen, N. S., et al. (2004). MIRAGE: Model description and evaluation of aerosols and trace gases. Journal of Geophysical Research: Atmospheres, 109(D20), 1–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Edenhofer, O., Bauer, N., & Kriegler, E. (2005). The impact of technological change on climate protection and welfare: Insights from the model MIND. Ecological Economics, 54(2–3), 277–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Edenhofer, O., Lessmann, K., & Bauer, N. (2006). Mitigation strategies and costs of climate protection: The effects of ETC in the hybrid model MIND. The Energy Journal, 0, 207–222.Google Scholar
- Eyckmans, J., & Tulkens, H. (2006). Simulating coalitionally stable burden sharing agreements for the climate change problem. In P. Chander, J. Drèze, C. K. Lovell, & J. Mintz (Eds.), Public goods, environmental externalities and fiscal competition (pp. 218–249). Boston: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Finus, M. (2000). Game theory and international environmental co-operation: A survey with an application to the kyoto-protocol. Milan: Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei.Google Scholar
- Gerlagh, R., & Kuik, O. (2014). Spill or leak? Carbon leakage with international technology spillovers: A CGE analysis. Energy Economics, 45, 381–388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Grubb, M. (1993). The costs of climate change: Critical elements. In Costs, Impacts, and Benefits of CO2 Mitigation (153–166). IIASA Collaborative Paper Series, CP93-2, Laxenburg, Austria.Google Scholar
- Grüning, C., & Peters, W. (2010). Can justice and fairness enlarge international environmental agreements? Games, 1(2), 137–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hertel, T. W. (1997). Global trade analysis: Modeling and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- Jacoby, H. D., Reilly, J. M., McFarland, J. R., & Paltsev, S. (2006). Technology and technical change in the MIT EPPA model. Energy Economics, 28(5–6), 610–631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kehoe, T. J., Levine, D. K., & Romer, P. M. (1992). On characterizing equilibria of economies with externalities and taxes as solutions to optimization problems. Economic Theory, 2(1), 43–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kypreos, S., & Bahn, O. (2003). A MERGE model with endogenous technological progress. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 8(3), 249–259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Laborde, D., & Valin, H. (2012). Modeling land-use changes in a global CGE: Assessing the EU biofuel mandates with the MIRAGE-BioF model. Climate Change Economics, 3(03), 1250017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Luo, Z.-Q., Pang, J.-S., & Ralph, D. (1996). Mathematical programs with equilibrium constraints. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Manne, A., Mendelsohn, R., & Richels, R. (1995). MERGE: A model for evaluating regional and global effects of GHG reduction policies. Energy Policy, 23(1), 17–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Morris, J., Paltsev, S., & Reilly, J. (2012). Marginal abatement costs and marginal welfare costs for greenhouse gas emissions reductions: Results from the EPPA model. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 17(4), 325–336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Nagashima, M., Dellink, R., Van Ierland, E., & Weikard, H.-P. (2009). Stability of international climate coalitions: A comparison of transfer schemes. Ecological Economics, 68(5), 1476–1487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Nijkamp, P., Wang, S., & Kremers, H. (2005). Modeling the impacts of international climate change policies in a CGE context: The use of the GTAP-E model. Economic Modelling, 22(6), 955–974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Nordhaus, W. D. (1991). To slow or not to slow: The economics of the greenhouse effect. The Economic Journal, 101(407), 920–937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Olesen, J. E., & Bindi, M. (2002). Consequences of climate change for European agricultural productivity, land use and policy. European Journal of Agronomy, 16(4), 239–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ortiz, R. A., & Markandya, A. (2009). Integrated impact assessment models of climate change with an emphasis on damage functions: A literature review, Working Paper, 06-2009, Basque Center for Climate Change, Spain.Google Scholar
- Paltsev, S., Reilly, J. M., Jacoby, H. D., Eckaus, R. S., McFarland, J. R., Sarofim, M. C., Asadoorian, M. O., & Babiker, M. H. M. (2005). The MIT emissions prediction and policy analysis (EPPA) model: Version 4. Technical report, MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change.Google Scholar
- Perman, R., Ma, Y., McGilvray, J., & Common, M. (2003). Natural resource and environmental economics (3rd ed.). London: Pearson Education.Google Scholar
- Piao, S., Ciais, P., Huang, Y., Shen, Z., Peng, S., Li, J., et al. (2010). The impacts of climate change on water resources and agriculture in China. Nature, 467(7311), 43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Rogna, M. (2016). Cooperative game theory applied to IEAs: A comparison of solution concepts. Journal of Economic Surveys, 30(3), 649–678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Sartzetakis, E. S., & Strantza, S. (2013). International environmental agreements: An emission choice model with abatement technology. Technical report 5/2013, University of Macedonia.Google Scholar
- Schlenker, W., & Lobell, D. B. (2010). Robust negative impacts of climate change on African agriculture. Environmental Research Letters, 5(1), 014010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tol, R. S. J. (2009). The economic effects of climate change. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(2), 29–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Varian, H. R. (1994). A solution to the problem of externalities when agents are well-informed. The American Economic Review, 84, 1278–1293.Google Scholar
- Vrontisi, Z., Abrell, J., Neuwahl, F., Saveyn, B., & Wagner, F. (2016). Economic impacts of EU clean air policies assessed in a CGE framework. Environmental Science & Policy, 55, 54–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Wei, W., Wen, C., Cui, Q., & Xie, W. (2018). The impacts of technological advance on agricultural energy use and carbon emission: An analysis based on GTAP-E model. Journal of Agrotechnical Economics, 2, 003.Google Scholar
- Yu, L., & Peng, S. (2017). Assessment and prediction of the impact of trade liberalization on China’s carbon emission: Empirical studies based on the GTAP-MRIO model and the GTAP-E model. Journal of International Trade, 8, 011.Google Scholar