Abstract
This work deals with the regulation of water pollution caused by the use of nitrogen in agriculture. We investigate the policy instruments that should be implemented to induce socially optimal water quality. To do so, we propose a dynamic theoretical framework. We focus on the potential of cover crops to preserve water quality by considering the impact of soil quality on water quality to be endogenous: we consider two interrelated dynamic equations, one for soil quality and one for water pollution, that interact through soil quality. The land area devoted to cover crops increases the soil quality stock which, in turn, decreases the water pollution stock. We show that the socially optimal fiscal scheme consists in two parts: one that acts at the intensive margin (proportional to nitrogen use) and one at the extensive margin (proportional to land cultivated with cover crops).
Keywords
Water quality Nitrate Soil quality Land-use tax Cover cropNotes
References
- 1.Amundson, R., & et al. (2015). Soil and human security in the 21st century. Science, 348(6235), 647–654.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 2.Burt, O.R. (1981). Farm level economics of soil conservation in the palouse area of the northwest. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 63(1), 83–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 3.Conrad, J.M., & Olson, L.J. (1992). The economics of stock pollutant: Aldicarb on Long Island. Environmental and Resource Economics, 3, 245–258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 4.Council of the European Communities. (1991). Council Directive 91/676/EEC of 12 December 1991 concerning the protection of waters against pollution caused by nitrates from agricultural sources.Google Scholar
- 5.Cumming, R. (1971). Optimum exploitation of groundwater reserves with saltwater intrusion. Water Resources Research, 7(6), 1415–14A23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 6.Dockner, E. (1985). Local stability analysis in optimal control problems with two state variables. In Feichtinger, G. (Ed.) Optimal control theory and economic analysis 2 (pp. 89–103). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
- 7.Goetz, R.U., & Zilberman, D. (1995). Mining the soil: agricultural production system on peatland. Environmental and Resource Economics, 6, 119–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 8.Goetz, R.U. (1997). Diversification in agricultural production: a dynamic model of optimal cropping to manage soil erosion. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79, 341–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 9.Goetz, R.U., & et al. (2006). Determining the economic gains from regulation at the extensive and intensive margins. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 33(1), 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 10.Hediger, W. (2003). Sustainable farm income in the presence of soil erosion: an agricultural Hartwick rule. Ecological Economics, 45, 1–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 11.Jayet, P.-A., & Petsakos, A. (2013). Evaluating the efficiency of a uniform N-input tax under different policy scenarios at different scales. Environmental Modelling and Assessment, 18, 57–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 12.Justes, E. (2017). Cover crops for sustainable farming. Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 13.Kaspar, T.C., & Singer, J.W. (2011). The use of cover crops to manage soil. In Hatfild, J.L., & Sauer, T.J. (Eds.) Soil management: building a stable base for agriculture. Madison, WI: American Society of Agronomy and Soil Science Society of America.Google Scholar
- 14.Kling, C.L., & et al. (2014). LUMINATE: Linking agricultural land use, local water quality and Gulf of Mexico Hypoxia. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 41(3), 431–459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 15.Langyintuo, A.S., & et al. (2005). Yield and income risk-efficiency analysis of alternative systems for rice production in the Guinea Savannah of Northern Ghana. Agricultural Economics, 32, 141–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 16.Legras, S. (2010). Managing correlated stock externalities: water taxes with a pinch of salt. Environment and Development Economics, 15(3), 275–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 17.Léonard, D., & Van Long, N. (1998). Optimal control theory and static optimization in economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- 18.Lichtenberg, E. (1989). Land quality, irrigation development and cropping patterns in the Northern High Plains. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 71(1), 187–194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 19.Loehman, E.T., & Randhir, T.O. (1999). Alleviating soil erosion/pollution stock externalities: alternative roles for government. Ecological Economics, 30, 29–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 20.McConnell, K. (1983). An economic model of soil conservation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 65(1), 83–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 21.Phaneuf, D.J., & Requate, T. (2017). A course in environmental economics - theory, policy and practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- 22.Roseta-Palma, C. (2002). Groundwater management when water quality is endogenous. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 44, 93–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 23.Schipanski, M.E., & et al. (2014). A framework for evaluating ecosystem services provided by cover crops in agroecosystems. Agricultural Systems, 125, 12–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 24.Sutton, M., & et al. (2011). The european nitrogen assessment: sources, effects and policy perspectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 25.Xabadia, A., & et al. (2008). The gains from differentiated policies to control stock pollution when producers are heterogeneous. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 90(4), 1059–1073.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 26.Xepapadeas, A. (1996). Quantity and quality management of groundwater: an application to irrigated agriculture in Iraklion, Crete. Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 1, 25–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 27.Yadav, S.N. (1997). Dynamic optimization of nitrogen use when groundwater contamination is internalized at the standard in the long run. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79(3), 31–945.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 28.Zeitouni, N., & Dinar, A. (1997). Mitigating negative water quality and quality externalities by joint management of adjacent aquifers. Environmental and Resource Economics, 9, 1–20.Google Scholar