Advertisement

Economic Theory

, Volume 67, Issue 1, pp 155–177 | Cite as

Real transfers and the Friedman rule

  • Bernardino Adão
  • André C. SilvaEmail author
Research Article
  • 156 Downloads

Abstract

We find that the Friedman rule is not optimal with real government transfers and distortionary taxation. As transfers cannot be taxed, a positive nominal net interest rate is the indirect way to tax the additional income derived from transfers. This result holds for heterogeneous agents, standard homogeneous preferences, and constant returns to scale production functions. The presence of real transfers changes the standard optimal taxation result of uniform taxation. Higher transfers imply higher optimal inflation rates. We calibrate a model with transfers to the US economy and obtain optimal values for inflation substantially above the Friedman rule.

Keywords

Friedman rule Fiscal policy Monetary policy Taxes Transfers Inflation 

JEL Classification

E52 E62 E63 H21 

Notes

Acknowledgements

We are grateful for the comments and suggestions of Tiago Cavalcanti and two anonymous referees. We are also grateful for the discussions and suggestions of Carlos da Costa, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles.

References

  1. Adão, B., Silva, A.C.: Government financing, inflation, and the financial sector. Nova SBE Working Paper Series 621 (2018)Google Scholar
  2. Arbex, M.: A quantitative analysis of tax enforcement and optimal monetary policy. Macroecon. Dyn. 17(5), 1096–1117 (2013)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Atkinson, A.B., Stiglitz, J.E.: The structure of indirect taxation and economic efficiency. J. Publ. Econ. 1(1), 97–119 (1972).  https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(72)90021-7 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Attanasio, O.P., Guiso, L., Jappelli, T.: The demand for money, financial innovation, and the welfare cost of inflation: an analysis with household data. J. Polit. Econ. 110(2), 317–351 (2002).  https://doi.org/10.1086/338743 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Avery, R.V., Elliehausen, G.E., Kennickell, A.B., Spindt, P.A.: The use of cash and transaction accounts by American families. Fed. Reserve Bull. 72(3), 179–196 (1987)Google Scholar
  6. Carey, D., Rabesona, J.: Tax ratios on labour and capital income and on consumption. OECD Econ. Stud. 35(2002/2), 129–174 (2002)Google Scholar
  7. Castañeda, A., Díaz-Giménez, J., Ríos-Rull, J.: Accounting for the U.S. earnings and wealth inequality. J. Polit. Econ. 111(4), 818–857 (2003).  https://doi.org/10.1086/375382 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Cavalcanti, T.V.V., Villamil, A.P.: Optimal inflation tax and structural reform. Macroecon. Dyn. 7(3), 333–362 (2003).  https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100502020096 Google Scholar
  9. Chari, V., Christiano, L.J., Kehoe, P.J.: Optimality of the Friedman rule in economies with distorting taxes. J. Monet. Econ. 37(2), 203–223 (1996).  https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(96)90034-3 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Chari, V., Kehoe, P.J.: Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. In: Taylor, J.B., Woodford, M. (eds.) Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1C, chap. 26, pp. 1671–1745. Elsevier, Amsterdam (1999).  https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0048(99)10039-9
  11. Cooley, T.F., Hansen, G.D.: The welfare costs of moderate inflations. J. Money Credit Bank. 23(3), 483–503 (1991). http://www.jstor.org/stable/1992683
  12. Cooley, T.F., Hansen, G.D.: Tax distortions in a neoclassical monetary economy. J. Econ. Theory 58(2), 290–316 (1992).  https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(92)90056-N CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Correia, I.: Consumption taxes and redistribution. Am. Econ. Rev. 100(4), 1673–1694 (2010).  https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.4.1673 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Correia, I., Teles, P.: The optimal inflation tax. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 2(2), 325–346 (1999).  https://doi.org/10.1006/redy.1998.0040 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Cunha, A.B.: The optimality of the friedman rule when some distorting taxes are exogenous. Econ. Theor. 35(2), 267–291 (2008).  https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-007-0236-5 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Diaz-Gimenez, J., Glover, A., Rios-Rull, J.V.: Facts on the distributions of earnings, income, and wealth in the united states: 2007 update. Fed. Reserve Bank Minneap. Q. Rev. 34(1), 2–31 (2011)Google Scholar
  17. Erosa, A., Ventura, G.: On inflation as a regressive consumption tax. J. Monet. Econ. 49(4), 761–795 (2002).  https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00115-0 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Friedman, M.: The optimum quantity of money. In: Friedman, M. (ed.) The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, pp. 1–50. Aldine, Chicago (1969)Google Scholar
  19. Kennickell, A.B., Starr-McCluer, M., Sunden, A.E.: Family finances in the US: recent evidence from the survey of consumer finances. In: Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 83, pp. 1–24 (1997)Google Scholar
  20. Kimbrough, K.P.: The optimum quantity of money rule in the theory of public finance. J. Monet. Econ. 18(3), 277–284 (1986).  https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(86)90040-1 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Lucas Jr., R.E., Stokey, N.L.: Optimal fiscal and monetary policy in an economy without capital. J. Monet. Econ. 12(1), 55–93 (1983).  https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(83)90049-1 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Mendoza, E.G., Razin, A., Tesar, L.L.: Effective tax rates in macroeconomics: cross-country estimates of tax rates on factor incomes and consumption. J. Monet. Econ. 34(3), 297–323 (1994).  https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(94)90021-3 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Mulligan, C.B., Sala-i-Martin, X.: Extensive margins and the demand for money at low interest rates. J. Polit. Econ. 108(5), 961–991 (2000).  https://doi.org/10.1086/317676 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Nicolini, J.P.: Tax evasion and the optimal inflation tax. J. Dev. Econ. 55(1), 215–232 (1998).  https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3878(97)00063-1 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Phelps, E.S.: Inflation in the theory of public finance. Swed. J. Econ. 75(1), 67–82 (1973). http://www.jstor.org/stable/3439275
  26. Ramsey, F.P.: A contribution to the theory of taxation. Econ. J. 37(145), 47–61 (1927). http://www.jstor.org/stable/2222721
  27. Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M.: Optimal fiscal and monetary policy under imperfect competition. J. Macroecon. 26(2), 183–209 (2004).  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2003.11.002 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M.: The optimal rate of inflation. In: Friedman, B.M., Woodford, M. (eds.) Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 3B, chap. 13, pp. 653–722. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2010).  https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-444-53454-5.00001-3
  29. Silva, A.C.: Taxes and labor supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States. Port. Econ. J. 7(2), 101–124 (2008).  https://doi.org/10.1007/s10258-008-0029-1 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Silva, A.C.: Rebalancing frequency and the welfare cost of inflation. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 4(2), 153–183 (2012).  https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.4.2.153 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Werning, I.: Optimal fiscal policy with redistribution. Quart. J. Econ. 122(3), 925–967 (2007). http://www.jstor.org/stable/25098865

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag GmbH Germany, part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Departamento de Estudos Económicos (DEE)Banco de PortugalLisbonPortugal
  2. 2.Nova School of Business and EconomicsUniversidade NOVA de LisboaLisbonPortugal

Personalised recommendations