Advertisement

Empirical Economics

, Volume 57, Issue 2, pp 475–503 | Cite as

Consumption and credit constraints: a model and evidence from Ireland

  • Petra Gerlach-Kristen
  • Rossana MerolaEmail author
Article

Abstract

After the onset of the financial crisis, consumption fell in many economies. This paper presents a small-scale DSGE model with occasionally binding credit constraints. Indebted households start facing credit constraints when the value of their main asset, housing, declines. As a response, they stop smoothing consumption and start deleveraging. Even households that only expect to face a credit constraint in the future deleverage. Using the Irish Household Budget Survey, we show that most Irish households continued to smooth consumption during the crisis. However, for highly indebted consumption smoothing is disrupted during the crisis. Households with leverage close to but below the standard loan-to-value ratio of 85% also seem to smooth consumption less than normal households. This is rational if they expect a further house price decline and therefore anticipate the need to deleverage in the near future. We interpret these results as evidence of credit constraints that arise from falling property prices.

Keywords

Occasionally binding credit constraint Housing collateral Mortgage markets DSGE Ireland 

JEL Classification

D11 D12 E21 E32 R21 

References

  1. Adjemian S, Bastani H, Karamé F, Juillard M, Maih J, Mihoubi F, Perendia G, Pfeifer J, Ratto M, Villemot S (2011) Dynare: reference manual version 4. Dynare working papers 1, CEPREMAPGoogle Scholar
  2. Agarwal S, Liu C, Souleles N (2007) The reaction of consumer spending and debt to tax rebates-evidence from consumer credit data. J Polit Econ 115(6):986–1019Google Scholar
  3. Alessie R, Devereux M, Weber G (1997) International consumption, durables and liquidity constraints: a cohort analysis. Eur Econ Rev 41:37–59Google Scholar
  4. Almeida H, Campello M, Liu C (2006) The financial accelerator: evidence from international housing markets. Rev Finance 10:321–352Google Scholar
  5. Angelini P, Neri S, Panetta F (2011) Monetary and macroprudential policies. Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 801, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations AreaGoogle Scholar
  6. Arellano C, Mendoza E (2002) Credit frictions and ‘sudden stops’ in small open economies: an equilibrium business cycle framework for emerging markets crises. NBER working paper 8880Google Scholar
  7. Attanasio O, Pavoni N (2011) Risk sharing in private information models with asset accumulation: explaining the excess smoothness of consumption. Econometrica 79:1027–1068Google Scholar
  8. Bank of International Settlements (2001) 71st annual report, June 2001, BaselGoogle Scholar
  9. Barakova I, Calem P, Wachter S (2014) Borrowing constraints during the housing bubble. J Hous Econ 24(c):4–20Google Scholar
  10. Beaudry P, Portier F (2006) Stock prices, news, and economic fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 96(4):1293–1307Google Scholar
  11. Beaudry P, Portier F (2014) News-driven business cycles: insights and challenges. J Econ Lit 52(4):993–1074Google Scholar
  12. Benigno G, Chen H, Otrok C, Rebucci A, Young E (2012) Optimal policy with occasionally binding constraints. CEP discussion paper 1172Google Scholar
  13. Berben RP, Bernoth K, Mastrogiacomo M (2007) Households’ response to wealth changes: do gains or losses make a difference? In: Bank for International Settlements (ed), Proceedings of the IFC conference on “measuring the financial position of the household sector”, Basel, 30–31 Aug 2006Google Scholar
  14. Beznoska M, Ochmann R (2012) Liquidity constraints and the permanent income hypothesis. DIW discussion paper 1231Google Scholar
  15. Beznoska M, Ochmann R (2013) The interest elasticity of household savings: a structural approach with German micro data. Empir Econ 45(1):371–399Google Scholar
  16. Blundell R, Pistaferri L, Preston I (2008) Consumption inequality and partial insurance. Am Econ Rev 98(5):1887–1921Google Scholar
  17. Blundell R, Pistaferri L, Saporta-Eksten I (2016) Consumption inequality and family labour supply. Am Econ Rev 106(2):387–435Google Scholar
  18. Brzoza-Brzezina M, Kolasa M, Krzysztof M (2015) A penalty function approach to occasionally binding credit constraints. Econ Model 51(c):317–327Google Scholar
  19. Callan T, Nolan B, Keane C, Savage M, Walsh JR (2014) Crisis, response and distributional impact: the case of Ireland. IZA J Eur Labor Stud 3(1):1–17Google Scholar
  20. Campbell J, Deaton A (1989) Why is consumption so smooth? Rev Econ Stud 56(3):357–373Google Scholar
  21. Campbell J, Mankiw G (1990) Permanent income, current income, and consumption. J Bus Econ Stat 8(3):265–279Google Scholar
  22. Carroll CD (1992) The buffer-stock theory of saving: some macroeconomic evidence. Brook Pap Econ Act 2:61–156Google Scholar
  23. Carroll CD, Kimball MS (2001) Liquidity constraints and precautionary saving. NBER working paper 8496Google Scholar
  24. Carroll CD, Toche P (2009) A tractable model of buffer stock saving. NBER working paper 15265Google Scholar
  25. Casado GarcÍa JM (2011) From income to consumption: measuring households partial insurance. Empir Econ 40(2):471–495Google Scholar
  26. Central Statistics Office (2013) Quarterly National Household Survey: effect on households of the economic downturnGoogle Scholar
  27. Christensen I, Meh C (2011) Countercyclical loan-to-value-ratios and monetary policy. Bank of Canada Mimeo, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  28. Christiano LJ, Fisher JDM (2000) Algorithms for solving dynamic models with occasionally binding constrain. J Econ Dyn Control 24(8):1179–1232Google Scholar
  29. Christiano LJ, Eichenbaum M, Evans C (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J Polit Econ 113:1–45Google Scholar
  30. Clancy D, Merola R (2017) Countercyclical capital rules for small open economies. J Macroecon 54:332–351Google Scholar
  31. Cogan JF, Cwik T, Taylor JB, Wieland V (2010) New Keynesian versus old Keynesian government spending multipliers. J Econ Dyn Control 34(3):281–295Google Scholar
  32. Deaton A (1991) Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica 59(5):1221–1248Google Scholar
  33. Deidda M (2014) Precautionary saving under liquidity constraints: evidence from Italy. Empir Econ 46(1):329–360Google Scholar
  34. Duffy D, O’Hanlon N (2013) Negative equity in the Irish housing market: estimates using loan level data. ESRI working paper 463Google Scholar
  35. Engelhardt GV (1996) House prices and home owner saving behavior. Reg Sci Urban Econ 26(3/4):313–336Google Scholar
  36. Erceg C, Guerrieri L, Gust C (2006) SIGMA: a new open economy model for policy analysis. Int J Cent Bank 2(1):1–50Google Scholar
  37. European Central Bank (2009) Housing wealth and private consumption in the euro area. Monthly Bulletin, Jan 2009Google Scholar
  38. Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network (2009) Survey data on household finance and consumption: research summary and policy use. European central bank occasional paper series no. 100Google Scholar
  39. Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network (2013) The eurosystem household finance and consumption survey: the results from the first wave. European Central Bank statistic paper series no. 2Google Scholar
  40. Flavin M (1981) The adjustment of consumption to changing expectations about future income. J Polit Econ 89(5):974–1009Google Scholar
  41. Flavin M (1985) Excess sensitivity of consumption to current income: liquidity constraints or myopia? Can J Econ 18(1):117–136Google Scholar
  42. Friedman M (1957) A theory of the consumption function. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  43. Gerlach-Kristen P (2013) The effect of unemployment, arrears and negative equity on consumption: Ireland in 2009/10. ESRI working paper 457Google Scholar
  44. Gerlach-Kristen P (2014) Testing the permanent income hypothesis for Irish households, 1994 to 2005. Econ Soc Rev 45(4):511–535Google Scholar
  45. Gerlach-Kristen P, Merola R, O’Toole C (2013) Consumption and credit constraint during financial crises. VoxEu, 1 Dec 2013Google Scholar
  46. Gomes S, Jacquinot P, Pisani M (2012) The EAGLE. A model for policy analysis of macroeconomic interdependence in the euro area. Econ Model 29(5):1686–1714Google Scholar
  47. Goodhart C, Hofmann B (2007) House prices and the macroeconomy: implications for banking and price stability. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  48. Guerrieri L, Iacoviello M (2015a) OccBin: a toolkit for solving dynamic models with occasionally binding constraints easily. Journal of Monetary Economics 70(C):22–38Google Scholar
  49. Guerrieri L, Iacoviello M (2015b) Collateral constraints and macroeconomic asymmetries. National Bank of Poland working papers 202Google Scholar
  50. Guerrieri V, Lorenzoni G (2011) Credit crises, precautionary savings and the liquidity trap. NBER working paper 17583Google Scholar
  51. Hall RE (1978) Stochastic implications of the life cycle-permanent income hypothesis: theory and evidence. J Polit Econ 86:971–987Google Scholar
  52. Hayashi F (1982) The permanent income hypothesis: estimation and testing by instrumental variables. J Polit Econ 90:895–916Google Scholar
  53. Hogan V, O’Sullivan P (2007) Consumption and house prices in Ireland. ESRI Quarterly Economic Commentary, SeptGoogle Scholar
  54. Honohan P (2009) Resolving Ireland’s banking crises. Paper prepared for the UCD-Dublin economic workshop conference: “responding to the crisis”, Dublin, 12 Jan 2009Google Scholar
  55. Iacoviello M (2005) House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. Am Econ Rev 95(3):739–764Google Scholar
  56. Iacoviello M, Neri S (2010) Housing market spillovers: evidence from an estimated DSGE model. Am Econ J Macroecon 2(2):125–164Google Scholar
  57. International Monetary Fund (2000) World Economic Outlook, May 2000, Washington D.CGoogle Scholar
  58. Jaimovich N, Rebelo S (2009) Can news about the future drive the business cycle? Am Econ Rev 99(4):1097–1118Google Scholar
  59. Jappelli T (1990) Who is credit constrained in the U.S. economy? Q J Econ 105(1):219–234Google Scholar
  60. Jappelli T, Pistaferri L (2010) The consumption response to income changes. Ann Rev Econ 2(1):479–506Google Scholar
  61. Jappelli T, Pistaferri L (2014) Fiscal policy and MPC heterogeneity. Am Econ J Macroecon 6(4):107–136Google Scholar
  62. Johnson D, Parker J, Souleles N (2006) Household expenditure and the income tax rebates of 2001. Am Econ Rev 96(5):1589–1610Google Scholar
  63. Jordà O, Schularick M, Taylor AM (2013) When credit bites back. J Money Credit Bank 45(S2):3–28Google Scholar
  64. Jordà O, Schularick M, Taylor AM (2015) Leveraged bubbles. J Monet Econ 76(S):S1–S20Google Scholar
  65. Justiniano A, Primiceri G, Tambalotti A (2015) Household leveraging and deleveraging. Rev Econ Dyn 18(1):3–20Google Scholar
  66. Kennedy G, McIndoe-Calder T (2012) The Irish mortgage market: stylised facts, negative equity and arrears. Quarterly Bulletin 01, Central Bank of IrelandGoogle Scholar
  67. Kim JR, Chung K (2016) The role of house price in the US business cycle. Empir Econ 51(1):71–92Google Scholar
  68. Krueger D, Perri F (2011) How do households respond to income shocks? 2009 Meeting paper 14, society for economic dynamicsGoogle Scholar
  69. Krueger D, Perri F, Pistaferri L, Violante G (2010) Cross sectional facts for macroeconomists. Rev Econ Dyn 13(1):1–14Google Scholar
  70. Kumhof M, Laxton D, Muir D, Mursula S (2010) The global integrated monetary and fiscal model: theoretical structure. IMF working paper WP/10/34Google Scholar
  71. Lalonde R, Muir D (2007) The Bank of Canada’s version of the global economy model (BoC-GEM). Bank of Canada technical report no. 98Google Scholar
  72. Lambertini L, Mendicino C, Punzi MT (2013) Leaning against boom-bust cycles in credit and housing prices. J Econ Dyn Control 37(8):1500–1522Google Scholar
  73. Lawless M, Lydon R, McIndoe-Calder T (2015) The financial position of Irish households. Quarterly Bulletin 01, Central Bank of IrelandGoogle Scholar
  74. Leland HE (1968) Saving and uncertainty: the precautionary demand for saving. Q J Econ 82(3):465–473Google Scholar
  75. Lorenzoni G (2009) A theory of demand shocks. Am Econ Rev 99(5):2050–2084Google Scholar
  76. Lydon R, O’Hanlon N (2012) Housing equity withdrawal, property bubbles and consumption. Central Bank of Ireland research technical paper 05/RT/12Google Scholar
  77. Mankiw NG, Shapiro MD (1985) Trends, random walks and tests of the permanent income hypothesis. J Monet Econ 16:165–174Google Scholar
  78. Mayer E, Gareis J (2013) What drives Ireland’s housing market? A Bayesian DSGE approach. Open Econ Rev 24:919–961Google Scholar
  79. McCarthy Y, McQuinn K (2013) Price expectations, distressed mortgage markets and the housing wealth effect. Central Bank of Ireland research technical papers 06/RT/13Google Scholar
  80. Mendoza EG (2010) Sudden stops, financial crises, and leverage. Am Econ Rev 100(5):1941–1966Google Scholar
  81. Mendoza EG, Smith K (2006) Quantitative implications of a debt-deflation theory of Sudden Stops and asset prices. J Int Econ 70(1):82–114Google Scholar
  82. Mian A, Sufi A (2010a) The Great Recession: lessons from microeconomic data. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 100:51–56Google Scholar
  83. Mian A, Sufi A (2010b) Household leverage and the recession of 2007–09. IMF Econ Rev 58:74–117Google Scholar
  84. Mian A, Sufi A (2014) House of debt: how they (and you) caused the Great Recession and how we can prevent it from happening again. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  85. Mian A, Rao K, Sufi A (2013) Household balance sheets, consumption and the economic slump. Q J Econ 128(4):1687–1726Google Scholar
  86. Miles D, Pillonca V (2008) Financial innovation and European housing and mortgage markets. Oxford Rev Econ Policy 24(1):145–175Google Scholar
  87. Nelson CR (1987) A reappraisal of recent tests of the permanent income hypothesis. J Polit Econ 95:641–646Google Scholar
  88. O’Connell B, O’Toole C, Znuderl N (2013) Trends in consumption since the crisis. ESRI Quarterly Economic Commentary, JanGoogle Scholar
  89. Ratto M, Roeger W, In ‘t Velt J (2009) QUEST III: an estimated open-economy DSGE model of the euro area with fiscal and monetary policy. Econ Model 26(1):222–233Google Scholar
  90. Roche MJ (1995) Testing the permanent income hypothesis: the Irish evidence. Econ Soc Rev 26(3):283–305Google Scholar
  91. Schmitt-Grohe S, Uribe M (2012) What’s news in business cycles. Econometrica 80:2733–2764Google Scholar
  92. Souleles N (2002) Consumer response to the Reagan tax cuts. J Public Econ 85:99–120Google Scholar
  93. Staunton C (2015) The distribution of wealth in Ireland, TASCGoogle Scholar
  94. Tobin J, Dolde W (1971) Wealth, liquidity, consumption. In: Consumer spending and monetary policy: the linkages. Federal Reserve Bank of BostonGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag GmbH Germany, part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Swiss National BankZurichSwitzerland
  2. 2.Research DepartmentInternational Labour OfficeGenevaSwitzerland

Personalised recommendations