Springer Nature is making SARS-CoV-2 and COVID-19 research free. View research | View latest news | Sign up for updates

Economic incentives for the self-regulation of the release of price-sensitive information

Abstract

Companies, as primary disseminators of information, and financial institutions, as major recipients, have economic incentives to self-regulate the transmission and usage of price-sensitive information. These include increased (lost) reputation costs and adverse share price penalties arising from poor management of information disclosure. The economic motivation for self-regulation is seen as conceptually linked to but distinct from legislative changes. Self-regulation has the strong support of economic efficiency arguments, whereas recent additional new legislative changes do not. This article examines a major corporate and institutional response to the new regulatory climate—to internalize part of the regulatory process during their regular relationship communications. Relationships between the case companies and institutions already exist for transaction purposes. They are used as a convenient and low-cost means to pursue self-regulation and to avoid errors of price-sensitive information release. This self-regulatory process is illustrated using case material. It is clear from the response pattern presented that the development of a self-regulatory framework by the parties has been an iterative one. The corporate and institutional systems that have been evolving seem to be significantly influenced by the regulatory trends. The regulatory changes appear to have played a role in increasing market costs incurred by those companies with poor stock market communication practices. The article ends by arguing that new proposals to change in the formal regulatory system should recognize that further legislation is unlikely to improve the poor prosecution record. Nevertheless, legislative changes can combine with and buttress the self-regulation process to create an effective regulatory system.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

References

  1. Bain, S. (1993).Scotland on Sunday, April 4, p. 15.

  2. Bain, S. (1994). “Business Week.”Scotland on Sunday, February 20, p. 2.The Economist. (1993). May 22, p. 100.

  3. Fenn, P., Alistair McGuire, and Dan Prentice. (1991). “Information Imbalances and the Security Markets.” InEuropean Insider Dealing (ch. 1). London: Butterworths.

  4. Franks, J., and S. Schaefer. (1994). “The Costs and Effectiveness of the U.K. Financial Regulatory System.” Paper presented at a workshop on the Assessment of Financial Markets Regulation. Regulatory Policy Research Centre, Hertford College, University of Oxford, September 12–14.

  5. London Stock Exchange. (1994a). “Guidance on the Dissemination of Price Sensitive Information.” February.

  6. London Stock Exchange. (1994b). “Orderly Markets: Dealings Ahead of the Disclosure of Price-Sensitive Information. October.

  7. Holland, J. and G. Stoner. (1995). “Corporate Problems with the Identification and Dissemination of Price-Sensitive Information.” BAA conference, Bristol, April (and University of Glasgow working paper).

  8. Hopwood, A. (1983). “On Trying to Study Accountancy in the Contexts in Which It Operates.”Accounting Organisations and Society 8, 287–305.

  9. Keenan. D. (1993). “New Rules for Insider Dealing.”Accountancy (December), 139.

  10. Kester, W. Carl. (1992). “Governance, Contracting, and Investment Horizons: A Look at Japan and Germany.”Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 5, (2) (Summer), 83–98.

  11. Large, A. (1994). “SIB Seeks Big Increase in Powers.”Independent, March 8, p. 25.

  12. Loomis, p. (1972). “Loomis on Inside Information.”Financial Analysts Journal 28(3) (May–June), 20–25. pp 82–88.

  13. Manne, R. (1966).Insider Trading and the Stock Market. New York: Free Press.

  14. Pozen, R. C. (1994). “Institutional Investors: The Reluctant Activists.”Harvard Business Review (January–February), 140–149.

  15. Rice, R. (1994). “Analysts Wary of Tighter Net.”Financial Times, March 22, p. 16.

  16. Rider, B. C. Abrams and E. Ferran. (1989).Guide to the Financial Services Act 1986 (2nd ed.) Bicester, Oxfordshire, UK: CCH Editions Ltd.

  17. Shackle, G. L. S. (1970).Expectation, Enterprise and Profit. London: George Allen and Unwin.

  18. Schmidt, H. (1991). “Insider Regulation and Economic Theory.”European Insider Dealing, (ch. 2). London: Butterworths.

  19. Scott, J. (1993). “Corporate Groups and Network Structures.” In J. McCahery, S. Picciotto, and C. Scott,Corporate Control and Accountability (ch. 16). Oxford Clarendon Press.

  20. Stephen, Frank. (1986). “Decision Making Under Uncertainty: In Defence of Shackle.”Journal of Economic Studies 13(5), 45–57.

  21. Scapens, R. W. (1990). “Researching Management Accounting Practice: The Role of Case Study Methods.”British Accounting Review 22, 259–281.

  22. Seyhun, H. N. (1992). “The Effectiveness of the Insider Trading Sanctions.”Journal of Law and Economics 35 April 1992, p 149–182.

  23. Shefrin, H., and M. Statman. (1993). “Ethics, Fairness and Efficiency in Financial Markets.”Financial Analysts Journal (November–December), 21–29.

Download references

Author information

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Holland, J. Economic incentives for the self-regulation of the release of price-sensitive information. Eur J Law Econ 3, 221–247 (1996). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00709141

Download citation

Keywords

  • Private disclosure
  • price sensitive information
  • economic incentive
  • self regulation