Skip to main content
Log in

From mixed economy to entangled political economy: a Paretian social-theoretic orientation

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper compares and contrasts two visions of political economy. These visions aren’t antagonistic, just different. The mixed economy vision associated with Ludwig von Mises and Sanford Ikeda treats politics as intervening into markets. The entangled political economy vision treats politics and markets as overlapping subsystems within a society. Entangled political economy thus descends from a theory of society and social processes. Similarly to quantum entanglement where the state of a particle cannot be described independently of that of other particles, entanglement in political economy means that rational market action cannot be defined independently of rational political action. The focal point of entangled political economy, moreover, is on individual actors and their search for gain within different action environments. Interaction among individuals across those environments generates societal tectonics, thereby adding insights from Vilfredo Pareto about social theory to those of Mises and Ikeda about interventionism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is opposed to dyadic exchange, whereby the two parties to the transaction necessarily are better off due to the exchange taking place.

  2. In this respect, Epstein (2006) pursues a research program of generating social configurations through interaction among individuals, in contrast to postulating the existence of those configurations as analytical primitives. Similarly, Aligica and Boettke (2009) explain that the analytical thrust of Elinor and Vincent Ostrom was to penetrate analytically into their material, in contrast to seeking to stand apart from that material.

  3. Aron (1967, pp. 101–176) summarizes Pareto’s Treatise lucidly, as does Bongiorno (1930). Campbell (1986) detects four distinct versions of Pareto in Aron’s long career where he returned to Pareto off and on. McLure (2007) surveys the relation between Pareto and the Italian tradition in the theory of public finance that was a precursor to public choice.

  4. With respect to market activity, there is clear feedback via the price mechanism that the means employed have a causal relationship with the ends attained. This is what Pareto meant in referring to market action as reflecting the logico-experimental method.

  5. An anonymous reviewer brought up the fact that credence goods, too, may be priced. Yet the feedback mechanism for credence goods is much less direct than it is for inspection and search goods.

  6. Total government spending as a percent of GDP accounts for more than 20 % of GDP, up from 3.4 % in 1930, and is projected to rise over the coming years (GPO 2015). Further, state and local spending ranges from a low of 14.3 % of GSP in South Dakota to a high of 26.7 % of GSP in Mississippi (Census 2012). This doesn’t even account for the burden that legislative and regulatory actions impose on the economy (Fichtner and McLaughlin 2015). Government participation in economic activity is clearly pervasive.

  7. Contrary to Caplan (2007), the resulting outcome need not be abject ignorance. The logical and non-logical domains are not commensurable, and with this non-commensurability being a source of boundary tectonics. Similar to Brennan and Lomasky (1993), voting is an expressive act within the Paretian analytical framework, though what resonates with voter sentiments is a challenge for political entrepreneurship in non-logical realms of action.

References

  • Aligica, P. D., & Boettke, P. J. (2009). Challenging institutional analysis and development: The Bloomington school. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aron, R. (1967). Main currents in sociological thought (Vol. II). New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Backhaus, J. G. (1978). Pareto and public choice. Public Choice, 33, 5–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becchio, G. (2014). Carl Menger on states as orders, not organizations: Entangled political economy into a neo-Mengerian approach. Advances in Austrian Economics, 18, 55–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berlin, I. (1969). Four essays on liberty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bongiorno, A. (1930). A study of Pareto’s treatise on general sociology. American Journal of Sociology, 36, 249–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K. E. (1956). The image: Knowledge in life and society. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision: The pure theory of electoral preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1967). Public finance in democratic process. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1968). The demand and supply of public goods. Chicago: Rand McNally.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The Samaritan’s dilemma. In E. Phelps (Ed.), Altruism, morality, and economic theory (pp. 71–85). New York: Russell Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, S. (1986). The four Paretos of Raymond Aron. Journal of the History of Ideas, 47, 287–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the rational voter. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2009). On the political economy of the financial crisis and bailout of 2008–2009. Public Choice, 140, 287–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. J. (2013). Doing bad by doing good: Why humanitarian action fails. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2001). The elusive quest for growth: Economists’ adventures and misadventures in the tropics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, R. A. (1993). Bargaining with the state. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, J. M. (Ed.). (2006). Generative social science. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eusepi, G., & Wagner, R. E. (2011). States as ecologies of political enterprises. Review of Political Economy, 23, 573–585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fichtner, J. J., & McLaughlin, P. A. (2015). Legislative impact accounting: rethinking how to account for policies’ economic costs in the federal budget process. Arlington, VA: Mercatus Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G. (2008). Rationality for mortals. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (2007 [1944]). The road to serfdom. London: Routledge.

  • Hume, D. (2000 [1748).) An enquiry concerning human understanding. New York: Oxford University Press.

  • Ikeda, S. (1997). The dynamics of the mixed economy: Toward a theory of interventionism. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda, S. (2005). The dynamics of interventionism. Advances in Austrian Economics, 8, 21–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Latour, B. (2005). Reassembling the social: An introduction to actor-network theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Littlechild, S. C. (1978). The fallacy of the mixed economy. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLure, M. (2007). The Paretian school and Italian fiscal sociology. Houndsmill: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. (1990 [1920]). Economic calculation in the socialist commonwealth. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Mises, L. (1996 [1929]). A critique of intervention. Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: Foundation for Economic Education.

  • Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78, 311–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pagenelli, M. P. (2014). Adam Smith and entangled political economy. Advances in Austrian Economics, 16, 37–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pantaleoni, M. (1911). Considerazioni sulle proprieta di un sistema di prezzi politici. Giornale degli Economisti, 42(9–29), 114–133.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. (1935 [1923]). The mind and society: A treatise on general sociology. New York: Harcourt Brace.

  • Podemska-Mikluch, M. (2014). Public policy: Object of choice or emergent phenomena? Advances in Austrian Economics, 18, 93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Podemska-Mikluch, M., & Wagner, R. E. (2013). Dyads, triads, and the theory of exchange: Between liberty and coercion. Review of Austrian Economics, 26, 171–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (2008). Rationality in economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A., Wagner, R. E., & Yandle, B. (2011). A theory of entangled political economy, with application to TARP and NRA. Public Choice, 148, 45–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Susskind, L., & Friedman, A. (2014). Quantum mechanics: The theoretical minimum. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi, V. (2011). Government versus markets: The changing economic role of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Census Bureau. (2012). Census of Governments: State and local finances. Retrieved from: http://www.census.gov/govs/local/.

  • U.S. Government Printing Office. (2014). Fiscal Year 2015 Historical Tables. Retrieved from: https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/budget/fy2015/assets/hist.pdf.

  • Viner, J. (1961). Hayek on freedom and coercion. Southern Economic Journal, 27, 230–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2007). Fiscal sociology and the theory of public finance. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2014). Entangled political economy: A keynotea address. Advances in Austrian Economics, 16, 15–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to the three referees who provided valuable suggestions that helped us to see more clearly than we had originally seen just what it was we were trying to accomplish in this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard E. Wagner.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Patrick, M., Wagner, R.E. From mixed economy to entangled political economy: a Paretian social-theoretic orientation. Public Choice 164, 103–116 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0273-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0273-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation