Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of within-party and between-party ideological dispersion on fiscal outcomes: evidence from Swiss cantonal parliaments

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The impact of the fragmentation of executive and legislative bodies on the level and composition of government expenditure is a feature of politics that has attracted considerable attention from economists. However, previous authors have abstracted from two important concepts: ideology and intra-party politics. In this paper, we account for these two phenomena explicitly, and make two main contributions. First, we show that both intra- and inter-party ideological dispersion matter in explaining the level of sub-national public spending. Therefore, it is improper to consider parties as monolithic entities. We also show that ideological dispersion matters especially for current expenditures, and not so much for investment expenditures. To do so, we construct a panel database (2003–2010) comprising data from a survey that quantifies the policy preferences of party members who were candidates in Swiss elections.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Short-lived minority governments and pacts occurred between 1974 and 1978 and in 1997 (Maer 2010).

  2. Australia had its first minority government in over 70 years in 2010, when the Labor Party and the coalition led by the liberals both failed to capture a majority of seats (Horne 2010). However, minority and coalition governments are more common in Australian sub-national jurisdictions. For its part, Canada was led by minority governments from 2004 to 2011 (the Parliament of Canada’s website has details on the length of all minority governments in Canadian history: http://www.parl.gc.ca/Parlinfo/compilations/parliament/DurationMinorityGovernment.aspx). Hung parliaments are more common in Canada than in Australia, although this 7-year-long string of minority governments was a first. Before that, a minority government ruled for 6 months in 1979.

  3. These authors use two measures of ideological polarization. The first is a variable describing the maximum distance between the governing parties (the executive party and the three main coalition partners) on the usual left–right scale (taking a value of two if one party is at the right end and another at the left end), while the second is the SD of the ideology of the three main governing parties.

  4. More recently, the emergence of the Tea Party, an American grassroots movement mostly associated with the Republican Party, is another example of a somewhat official faction, now even recognized as an official Congressional Member Organization (CMO). The relationship between the Tea Party movement in the public at large and the CMO is not clear, with many members of the former not recognizing the latter. However, the members of the CMO are supporters of the larger movement. Party factions also exist in France. Indeed, major French parties are characterized by smaller factions. For example, the Socialist Party has a social-democratic, more moderate branch, but also includes members of a more radical leftist tradition. Similarly, the Union pour un mouvement populaire is comprised of a socially conservative branch as well as a more market-oriented faction.

  5. Swiss sub-national governments enjoy full discretion on the tax rates and the levels of tax allowances and reliefs (reductions in the amount owed). For more details, see the OECD fiscal decentralisation database, available at http://www.oecd.org/tax/federalism/oecdfiscaldecentralisationdatabase.htm.

  6. Following the 2011 federal elections, close to one-third of the National Council members were new. At that date, the median tenure in parliament was slightly under 4 years, highlighting the fact that turnover is high in Swiss politics, at least at the federal level.

  7. The 2011 questionnaire is available on the Smartvote website at http://smartvote.ch/11_ch_nr/questionnaire.

  8. During the electoral campaign, voters can answer the same questionnaire on the Smartvote website and have their answers compared to those of the candidates. As a result, Smartvote matches each voter with a specific ranking of all competing candidates.

  9. Further details are provided in a longer version of this paper, available on request.

  10. The composition of the parliament varies following every cantonal election (or by-election), while ideology scores (the average score of, and variance within, each party) stay constant between each federal election. For this reason, our variables have at least some variation every year, if only for composition effects.

  11. The box plots for other cantons are available from the authors.

  12. Cantonal GDP data are not available for every year. We obtain data for GDP per capita from the Swiss Federal Statistical Office for 2003–2005. For the years from 2006 to 2010, we extrapolate the data using the national growth rate of GDP per capita, assuming that the growth rate is similar across cantons.

  13. To obtain a causal interpretation, researchers have turned in recent years to quasi-experimental methods such as instrumental variables or regression discontinuity designs. Obviously, we would welcome the use of such methods to study the relationship between ideological dispersion and fiscal outcomes. However, our specific framework does not allow for these. The presence of endogeneity not being obvious, we believe that our results, while needing to be interpreted with some caution, are still interesting.

  14. Ticino is an exception. For that canton, we are able to collect observations for 4 years only, thereby limiting the number of observations suitable for our model.

  15. Using the average exchange rate over the period, this amount corresponds to 490 euros or 635 US dollars.

  16. Using the average exchange rate over the period, this amount corresponds to 287 euros or 372 US dollars.

  17. The effect of intra-party dispersion is larger on spending per capita than on spending as a percentage of cantonal GDP, while the opposite is true for inter-party dispersion. It is unclear whether there is any significance in this result.

  18. The SVP is one of the largest parties at the federal level in Switzerland, as well as in many cantons.

References

  • Alesina, A., & Drazen, A. (1991). Why are stabilizations delayed. American Economic Review, 81(5), 1170–1188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Tabellini, G. (1990). A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. The Review of Economic Studies, 57(3), 403–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bachtiger, A., Schwarz, D., & Lutz, G. (2006). Parliamentary practices in presidentialism? A Swiss perspective on governance in a separation of powers framework. In Paper prepared for the Joint Sessions of the ECPR.

  • Back, H. (2008). Intra-party politics and coalition formation: Evidence from Swedish local government. Party Politics, 14(1), 71–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belloni, F. P., & Beller, D. C. (1976). The study of party factions as competitive political organizations. The Western Political Quarterly, 29(4), 531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bettcher, K. E. (2005). Factions of interest in Japan and Italy: The organizational and motivational dimensions of factionalism. Party Politics, 11(3), 339–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrubba, C. J., & Volden, C. (2000). Coalitional politics and logrolling in legislative institutions. American Journal of Political Science, 44(2), 255–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceron, A. (2011). Intra-party politics and party system. Factional conflict, cooperation and fission within Italian parties (PhD Thesis, Universitá degli Studi di Milano, 2011).

  • Church, C. H., & Vatter, A. (2009). Opposition in consensual Switzerland: A short but significant experiment. Government and Opposition, 44(4), 412–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Haan, J., & Sturm, J.-E. (1997). Political and economic determinants of OECD budget deficits and government expenditures: A reinvestigation. European Journal of Political Economy, 13(4), 739–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Haan, J., Sturm, J.-E., & Beekhuis, G. (1999). The weak government thesis: Some new evidence. Public Choice, 101(3), 163–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debus, M., & Bräuninger, T. (2009). Intra-party factions and coalition bargaining. In D. Giannetti & K. Benoit (Eds.), Intra-party politics and coalition government. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elgie, R., & McMenamin, I. (2008). Political fragmentation, fiscal deficits and political institutionalisation. Public Choice, 136(3), 255–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eslava, M., & Nupia, O. (2010). Political fragmentation and government spending: Bringing ideological polarization into the picture. Documentos CEDE Working Paper.

  • Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2000). Direct democracy, political culture, and the outcome of economic policy: A report on the Swiss experience. European Journal of Political Economy, 16(2), 287–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2006). On the effectiveness of debt brakes: The Swiss experience. CREMA Working Paper number 2006-21.

  • Feld, L., Kirchgässner, G., & Schaltegger, C. (2003). Decentralized taxation and the size of government: Evidence from Swiss state and local governments. CESifo Working Paper number 1087.

  • Freier, R., & Odendahl, C. (2012). Do absolute majorities spend less? Evidence from Germany. DIW Discussion Paper number 1239.

  • Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Deviations from constituent interests: The role of legislative structure and political parties in the states. Economic Inquiry, 33(3), 383–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golden, M. A., & Chang, E. C. C. (2011). Competitive corruption: Factional conflict and political malfeasance in postwar Italian Christian democracy. World Politics, 53(4), 588–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R., & von Hagen, J. (2009). Forms of fiscal governance. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hertig, H. P. (1978). Party cohesion in the Swiss Parliament. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 3(1), 63–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hetherington, M. J. (2006). Why trust matters: Declining political trust and the demise of American liberalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hix, S., Noury, A., & Roland, G. (2009). Voting patterns and alliance formation in the European Parliament. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society, 364(1518), 821–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horne, N. (2010). Hung parliaments and minority governments. Background Note (Australian Parliament).

  • Hug, S., & Schulz, T. (2007). Left–right positions of political parties in Switzerland. Party Politics, 13(3), 305–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeitzinger, B., & Hohl, T. (1997). Measuring political preferences: Ratings for members of the Swiss National Council. Swiss Political Science Review, 3(4), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerr, H. H. Jr. (1978). The structure of opposition in the Swiss Parliament. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 3(1), 51–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kontopoulos, Y., & Perotti, R. (1999). Government fragmentation and fiscal policy outcomes: Evidence from OECD countries. In J. M. Poterba (Ed.), Fiscal institutions and fiscal performance (pp. 81–102). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kriesi, H., & Trechsel, A. H. (2008). The politics of Switzerland: Continuity and change in a consensus democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Laakso, M., & Taagepera, R. (1979). Effective number of parties: A measure with application to west Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 12(1), 3–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ladner, A. (2001). Swiss political parties: Between persistence and change. West European Politics, 24(2), 123–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lanfranchi, P., & Luthi, R. (1999). Cohesion of party groups and interparty conflict in the Swiss Parliament: Roll call voting in the national council. In S. Bowler, D. M. Farrell & R. S. Katz (Eds.), Party discipline and parliamentary government. Columbus, OH: Ohio State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., & Shepsle, K. A. (1990). Government coalitions and intraparty politics. British Journal of Political Science, 20(4), 489–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindqvist, E., & Östling, R. (2010). Political polarization and the size of government. American Political Science Review, 104(3), 543–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maer, L. (2010). Hung parliaments. UK House of Commons Library Reports number SN/PC/04951.

  • Miller, N. R. (1999). Logrolling. In P. B. Clark and J. Foweraker (Eds.), The encyclopedia of democratic thought. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulas-Granados, C. (2003). The political and economic determinants of budgetary consolidation in Europe. European Political Economy Review, 1(1), 15–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Müller, W. C., & Strom, K. (2003). Coalition governments in western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Padovano, F., & Venturi, L. (2001). Wars of attrition in Italian government coalitions and fiscal performance: 1948–1994. Public Choice, 109(1), 15–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedersen, H. H. (2010). How intra-party power relations affect the coalition behaviour of political parties. Party Politics, 16(6), 737–754.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti, R., & Kontopoulos, Y. (2002). Fragmented fiscal policy. Journal of Public Economics, 86(2), 191–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Svensson, L. E. (1989). Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: Policy with time-inconsistent preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(2), 325–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. M. (1994). State responses to fiscal crises: The effects of budgetary institutions and politics. Journal of Political Economy, 102(4), 799–821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricciuti, R. (2004). Political fragmentation and fiscal outcomes. Public Choice, 118(3), 365–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roubini, N., & Sachs, J. D. (1989). Government spending and budget deficits in the industrial economies. NBER Working Paper number 2919.

  • Rowley, C. K., Shughart, W. F., & Tollison, R. D. (2002). The international library of critical writings in economics: The economics of budget deficits. Elgar.

  • Rudolph, T. J., & Evans, J. (2005). Political trust, ideology, and public support for government spending. American Journal of Political Science, 49(3), 660–671.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaltegger, C. A., & Feld, L. P. (2004). Do large cabinets favor large governments? Evidence from Swiss sub-federal jurisdictions. CESifo Working Paper Series number 1294.

  • Schwarz, D., Schädel, L., & Ladner, A. (2010). Pre-election positions and voting behaviour in parliament: Consistency among Swiss MPs. Swiss Political Science Review, 16(3), 533–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spolaore, E. (1993). Macroeconomic policy, institutions and efficiency (PhD Thesis, Harvard University, 1993).

  • Tavares, J. (2004). Does right or left matter? Cabinets, credibility and fiscal adjustments. Journal of Public Economics, 88(12), 2447–2468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volkerink, B., & De Haan, J. (2001). Fragmented government effects on fiscal policy: New evidence. Public Choice, 109(3), 221–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warwick, P. V. (2000). Policy horizons in west European parliamentary systems. European Journal of Political Research, 38(1), 37–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. The Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman, A. S. (1979). The politics of faction: Christian democratic rule in Italy. New York: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Julien Fiechter for access to data from Smartvote surveys, Mark Schelker for Swiss institutional data, as well as participants at the Sinergia seminar in St. Gallen, at a seminar at the University of Fribourg, three anonymous referees, Roger Couture, and the editor for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thierry Madiès.

Appendix: Results using total variance as the variable of interest

Appendix: Results using total variance as the variable of interest

See the Table 5.

Table 5 Regression results with total variances

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bjedov, T., Lapointe, S. & Madiès, T. The impact of within-party and between-party ideological dispersion on fiscal outcomes: evidence from Swiss cantonal parliaments. Public Choice 161, 209–232 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0149-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0149-8

Keywords

Navigation