Skip to main content
Log in

May increased partisanship lead to convergence of parties’ policy platforms?

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Parties face a trade-off between motivating partisans to participate in the election and appealing to issue-oriented middle-of-the-road voters. We show that, consequently, parties may diverge from the median voters’ preferred policy by sending ambiguous messages to voters which include announcements of alternative platforms. Moreover, surprisingly, an increase in the size of a partisan constituency may lead to platform convergence towards the median voters’ preferred policy. We identify two conditions for this outcome. First, the electorate is sufficiently divided such that full convergence does not occur and, second, the majority of the non-partisan voters is more inclined to the party with increased support of partisans.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abramowitz, A. I., & Saunders, K. L. (1998). Ideological realignment in the US electorate. Journal of Politics, 60, 634–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., & Merrill, S. (2003). Voter turnout and candidate strategies in American elections. Journal of Politics, 65, 161–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (1988). Credibility and policy convergence in a two-party system with rational voters. American Economic Review, 78, 796–805.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Cukierman, A. (1990). The politics of ambiguity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105, 829–850.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aragones, E., & Palfrey, T. R. (2002). Mixed equilibrium in a Downsian model with a favored candidate. Journal of Economic Theory, 103, 131–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, S. (2006). Campaign finance and voter welfare with entrenched incumbents. American Political Science Review, 100, 55–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, S., & Bueno de Mesquita, E. (2009). Elections with platform and valence competition. Games and Economic Behavior, 67, 191–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvert, R. L. (1985). Robustness of the multidimensional voting model: candidate motivations, uncertainty, and convergence. American Journal of Political Science, 29, 69–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A., Converse, P., Miller, W., & Stokes, D. (1960). The American Voter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrillo, J. D., & Castanheira, M. (2008). Information and strategic political polarization. Economic Journal, 118, 845–874.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coate, S. (2004). Pareto improving campaign finance policy. American Economic Review, 94, 628–655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A., & Tommasi, M. (1998a). When does it take a Nixon to go to China? American Economic Review, 88, 180–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A., & Tommasi, M. (1998b). Credibility of policymakers and of economic reforms:. In F. Sturzenegger & M. Tommasi (Eds.), The Political Economy of Reform. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1998). Ideology, tactics, and efficiency in redistributive politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 497–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eyster, E., & Kittsteiner, T. (2007). Party platforms in electoral competition with heterogeneous constituencies. Theoretical Economics, 2, 41–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L., & Ward, B. A. (2006). Myths and realities of American political geography. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 119–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L., Ponzetto, G. A. M., & Shapiro, J. M. (2005). Strategic extremism: why Republicans and Democrats divide on religious values. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 1283–1330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, S. (2004). Social identity theory and party identification. Social Science Quarterly, 85, 136–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T. J. (2001). A model of candidate location when one voter has a valence advantage. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 862–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral competition and special interest politics. Review of Economic Studies, 63, 265–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2001). Special Interest Politics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrera, H., Levine, D. K., & Martinelli, C. (2008). Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 501–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houser, D., & Stratmann, T. (2008). Selling favors in the lab: experiments on campaign finance reform. Public Choice, 136, 215–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimball, D. C., & Gross, C. A. (2007). The growing polarization of American voters. In J.C. Green (Ed.), The State of Parties (pp. 265–278). Boulder: Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laslier, J. (2000). Interpretation of electoral mixed strategies. Social Choice and Welfare, 17, 283–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarty, N., Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (2006). Polarized America: The Dance of Ideology and Unequal Riches. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G., & Schofield, N. J. (2003). Activists and partisan realignment in the United States. American Political Science Review, 97, 245–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plane, D. L., & Gershtenson, J. (2004). Candidates’ ideological locations, abstention, and turnout in U.S. midterm senate elections. Political Behavior, 26, 69–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prat, A. (2002). Campaign advertising and voter welfare. Review of Economic Studies, 69, 999–1018.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (1997a). Political-economic equilibrium when parties represent constituents: the unidimensional case. Social Choice and Welfare, 14, 479–502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (1997b). The democratic political economy of progressive income taxation. Econometrica, 67, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. J. (2003). Valence competition in the spatial stochastic model. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15, 371–383.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schreckhise, W. D., & Shields, T. G. (2003). Ideological realignment in the contemporary U.S. electorate revisited. Social Science Quarterly, 84, 596–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shachar, R. (2003). Party loyalty as habit formation. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18, 251–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (2005). Some talk: money in politics. A (partial) review of the literature. Public Choice, 124, 135–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (2006). Contribution limits and the effectiveness of campaign spending. Public Choice, 129, 461–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T., & Aparicio-Castillo, F. J. (2006). Competition policy for elections: do campaign contribution limits matter? Public Choice, 127, 177–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1983). Candidate motivation: a synthesis of alternative theories. American Political Science Review, 77, 142–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zakharov, A. (2009). A model of candidate location with endogenous valence. Public Choice, 138, 347–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zipp, J.F. (1985). Perceived representatives and voting: an assessment of the impact of “choices” vs. “echoes”. American Political Science Review, 79, 50–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Volker Grossmann.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Blumkin, T., Grossmann, V. May increased partisanship lead to convergence of parties’ policy platforms?. Public Choice 145, 547–569 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-009-9579-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-009-9579-8

JEL Classification

Navigation