Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Agricultural Exports, Tariffs and Growth

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article presents a Ricardian model of trade with learning-by-doing to study the effect of barriers to trade in products with low growth potential on the long-run economic growth. The model shows that, when elasticity of demand for the product with a lower learning potential is lower than unitary, a reduction in the tariff imposed on this product, may shift the demand toward the product with a higher learning potential, thus enhancing economic growth in the exporter economy. Therefore, the current trend of reduction in tariffs on agricultural exports not only generates a positive welfare effect in the short run, but may similarly be beneficial for developing economies in the long run, since it also increases their incentive to develop sectors with higher growth potential.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, however, Rodrik, Subrananian and Trebbi (2004) for a critical view.

  2. For further evidence on protection levels in agriculture before the Uruguay Round Agreement see, for example, Josling (1993).

  3. Thus, for example, while the World Bank’s Tariff Trade Restrictiveness Index (TTRI) for 2007 for agricultural exports from low-income countries is slightly lower than 10 %, the corresponding Overall Trade Restrictiveness Index (OTRI) is slightly higher than 25 % (World Bank 2010). For the role of sanitary and phytosanitary requirements in developed countries as barriers to agricultural exports from developing countries see, for instance, Henson and Loader (2001). A broader analysis of the consequences of agricultural trade liberalization for developing countries can be found, for example, in Bureau et al. (2006).

  4. With such pattern of comparative advantage, allowing for learning in the “foreign” sector in the less advanced economy will not generate additional insights.

  5. Since an increase in the foreign demand for the semi-sophisticated product is the driving force behind this paper’s main result, an alternative assumption of learning-by-exporting in this sector will yield a qualitatively similar result.

  6. For an analysis of the welfare implications of the distribution of tariff revenues see, for example, Galor (1994). Alogoskoufis (2014) shows that an economy that moves from autarky to openness will end up with a higher growth rate and a negative net external position if the world real interest rate is lower than its autarky equilibrium real interest rate.

  7. In Azarnert (2004) I consider the effect of the opportunities abroad for the high-skilled taxpayers on taxation and then economic growth. Cf. also Azarnert (2012) where further references can be found.

  8. Although, following Spilimbergo (2000), I adopt a Stone-Geary-type utility function, the same result could be obtained using any utility function with elasticity of substitution smaller than one.

  9. Formally, this condition implies that technological progress in sector y in the home country sets the upper bound for the tariffs imposed on the good produced in sector x. Recent models with an endogenous emergence of comparative advantages can be found, for instance, in Fajgelbaum, Grossman and Helpman (2011) and Jaimovich and Merella (2011).

  10. The steps to compute ω are:

    $$ \gamma \left(1-{P}_{xt}^HX\right)=\left[1-\gamma \left(1-{P}_{xt}^FX\right)\right] f\omega \Rightarrow \gamma \left(1-{a}_x^HX\right)=\left[1-\gamma \left(1-\frac{a_x^H\left(1+\tau \right)}{\omega }X\right)\right] f\omega . $$

    Solving this equality for ω gives equation (19).

  11. The total demand for y t is the sum of the demands in Home and in Foreign. The total demand for y t is:

    $$ {y}_t^{H, tr}+{y}_t^{F, tr}=\frac{\beta }{P_{yt}^H}\left(1-{P}_{xt}^HX\right)+\frac{\beta }{P_{yt}^F}\left(1-{P}_{xt}^FX\right)f $$
    $$ =\frac{\beta }{a_{yt}^H}\left(1-{a}_x^HX\right)+\frac{\beta \omega}{a_{yt}^F}\left(1-\frac{a_x^H\left(1+\tau \right)}{\omega }X\right)f=\frac{\beta }{a_{yt}^H}\left(1-{a}_x^HX\left(1+\left(1+\tau \right)f\right)+\omega f\right). $$

    Plugging in the equation for ω (19) and simplifying gives equation (23).

References

  • Alogoskoufis G (2014) Endogenous growth and external balance in a small open economy. Open Economies Review (Forthcoming)

  • Azarnert LV (2004) Redistribution, fertility, and growth: the effect of the opportunities abroad. Eur Econ Rev 48:785–795

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azarnert LV (2012) Guest-worker migration, human capital and fertility. Rev Dev Econ 16:318–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David D (1993) Equalizing exchange: trade liberalization and income convergence. Q J Econ 108:653–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bureau J-C, Jean S, Matthews A (2006) The consequences of agricultural trade liberalization for developing countries: distinguishing between genuine benefits and false hopes. World Trade Rev 5:225–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D (1992) Outward-oriented developing economies really do grow more rapidly: evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976–85. Econ Dev Cult Chang 40:523–544

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D, Kraay A (2004) Trade, growth, and poverty. Econ J 114:F22–F49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards S (1998) Openness, productivity and growth: what do we really know? Econ J 108:383–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fajgelbaum PD, Grossman GM, Helpman E (2011) Income distribution, product quality, and international trade. J Polit Econ 119:721–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Romer D (1999) Does trade cause growth? Am Econ Rev 89:379–399

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (1994) Tariffs, income distribution and welfare in small overlapping-generation economy. Int Econ Rev 35:173–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenaway D, Morgan W, Wright P (2002) Trade liberalization and growth in developing countries. J Dev Econ 67:229–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison A (1996) Openness and growth: a time-series, cross-country analysis for developing countries. J Dev Econ 48:419–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henson S, Loader R (2001) Barriers to agricultural exports from developing countries: the role of sanitary and phytosanitary requirement. World Dev 29:85–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaimovich E, Merella V, (2011) Love for quality, comparative advantages, and trade. Carlo Alberto Notebooks, no. 216

  • Josling T (1993) Protectionism in agriculture: Slow progress toward freer trade in agricultural products. Open Econ Rev 4:211–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger AO (1998) Why trade liberalization is good for growth? Econ J 108:1513–1522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1987) The narrow moving band, the Dutch Disease, and the competitive consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: Notes on trade in the presence of dynamic scale economies. J Dev Econ 27:41–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:3–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama K (1992) Agricultural productivity, comparative advantage, and economic growth. J Econ Theory 58:317–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs JD, Werner A (1995) Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:1–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Spilimbergo A (2000) Growth and trade: the North can lose. J Econ Growth 5:131–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wacziarg R, Welsh KH (2008) Trade liberalization and growth: new evidence. World Bank Econ Rev 22:187–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2010) World Development Indicators. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Leonid V. Azarnert.

Additional information

I thank Editor-in-Chief, George S. Tavlas, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments and suggestions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Azarnert, L.V. Agricultural Exports, Tariffs and Growth. Open Econ Rev 25, 797–807 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-013-9297-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-013-9297-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation