Skip to main content
Log in

Probabilities of Consistent Election Outcomes with Majorities Based on Difference in Support

  • Published:
Group Decision and Negotiation Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Computer simulations are used to evaluate the likelihood of consistent outcomes under the class of majorities based on difference in support. These majorities require certain consensus in collective preferences to declare an alternative as the winner. More precisely, individuals show preference intensities in the unit interval among each pair of alternatives and it is required that the winner alternative obtains a difference in the sum of the intensities with respect to the loser alternative. This difference is a real number located between 0 and the total number of voters. We introduce the values of the required threshold for which majorities based on difference in support lead to transitive and triple-acyclic collective decisions with a probability of 1. Our results improve the previous theoretical ones since they require softer thresholds to reach consistent collective decisions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To calculate the probabilities presented here, m takes the following values: 3, 4, 5, 10, 100, 1000 and 100,000.

  2. Assuming a proportion of consistent outcomes P on the population of a 50 %, the proportion p in a random sample of size \(n \ge 30\) for a confidence level of 99 %, diverges from the one of the population in an error of less than \(\epsilon \):

    $$\begin{aligned} Prob(|P-p|\le \epsilon ) \ge 0.99. \end{aligned}$$

    Taken into account that the sample proportion p is distributed as \(N\left( P, \sqrt{P(1 - P)/n} \right) \), the sampling error \(\epsilon \) is as follows:

    $$\begin{aligned} \epsilon = z_{\alpha /2}\sqrt{P(1 - P)/n}. \end{aligned}$$

    In our case, \(n=\)100,000 and the corresponding percentile of the normal distribution for a confidence level of 99 % is \(z_{\alpha /2}= 2.57\). Thus, \(\epsilon \le 0.00407\)

  3. Notice that \(m/3 = \lfloor (2\times 100)/3\rfloor /2\) when m is multiple of three.

References

  • Balasko Y, Crès H (1997) The probability of Condorcet cycles and super majority rules. J Econ Theory 75:237–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell CD, Tullock G (1965) A measure of the importance of cyclical majorities. Econ J 75(300):853–857

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cervone DP, Gehrlein WV, Zwicker WS (2005) Which scoring rule maximizes Condorcet efficiency under IAC? Theor Decis 58(2):145–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Condorcet MD (1785) Essai sur l’Application de l’Analyse à la Probabilité des Décisions Rendues à la Pluralité des Voix. Imprimerie Royale, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook WD, Kress M (1985) Ordinal ranking with intensity of preference. Manag Sci 31:26–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta M, Deb R (1996) Transitivity and fuzzy preferences. Soc Choice Welf 13(3):305–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeMeyer F, Plott C (1970) The probability of a cyclical majority. Econometrica 38(2):345–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diss M, Pérez-Asurmendi P (2015) Consistent collective decisions under majorities based on difference of votes. Theory Dec. doi:10.1007/s11238-015-9501-4

  • Dubois D, Prade H (1980) Fuzzy sets and systems: theory and applications. Mathematics in science and engineering. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn PC, Gehrlein WV (1980) The paradox of voting: effects of individual indifference and intransitivity. J Public Econ 14(1):83–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Lapresta JL, Llamazares B (2000) Aggregation of fuzzy preferences: some rules of the mean. Soc Choice Welf 17(4):673–690

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Lapresta JL, Llamazares B (2001) Majority decisions based on difference of votes. J Math Econ 35(3):463–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Lapresta JL, Llamazares B (2010) Preference intensities and majority decisions based on difference of support between alternatives. Group Decis Negot 19(6):527–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Lapresta JL, Meneses LC (2005) Individual-valued preferences and their aggregation: consistency analysis in a real case. Fuzzy Sets Syst 151(2):269–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein WV (1983) Condorcet’s paradox. Theor Decis 15(2):161–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein WV, Fishburn PC (1976) Condorcet’s paradox and anonymous preference profiles. Public Choice 26:1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein WV, Fishburn PC (1980) Robustness of positional scoring over subsets of alternatives. Appl Math Optim 6:241–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein WV, Fishburn PC (1981) Constant scoring rules for choosing one among many alternatives. Qual Quant 15:203–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein WV, Fishburn PC (1983) Scoring rule sensitivity to weight selection. Public Choice 40:249–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guilbaud G-TH (1952) Les théories de l’intérêt général et le problème logique de l’agrégation. Econ Appl 5:501–584

    Google Scholar 

  • Houy N (2007) Some further characterizations for the forgotten voting rules. Math Soc Sci 53(1):111–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones B, Radcliff B, Taber C, Timpone R (1995) Condorcet winners and the paradox of voting: probability calculations for weak preference orders. Am Polit Sci Rev 89(1):133–144

    Google Scholar 

  • Klahr D (1966) A computer simulation of the paradox of voting. Am Polit Sci Rev 60(2):384–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B (2004) Simple and absolute special majorities generated by OWA operators. Eur J Oper Res 158:707–720

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B (2006) The forgotten decision rules: majority rules based on difference of votes. Math Soc Sci 51(3):311–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B (2007) Choosing OWA operator weights in the field of social choice. Inf Sci 177:4745–4756

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B, García-Lapresta JL (2003) Voting systems generated by quasiarithmetic means and OWA operators. In: Fodor J, De Baets B (eds) Principles of fuzzy preference modelling and decision making. Academia, Press, Ghent, pp 195–213

    Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B, García-Lapresta JL (2008) Extension of some voting systems to the field of gradual preferences. In: Bustince H, Herrera F, Montero J (eds) Fuzzy sets and their extensions: representation, aggregation and models. Springer, Berlin, pp 297–315

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B, Pérez-Asurmendi P (2015) Triple-acyclicity in majorities based on difference in support. Inf Sci 299:209–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B, Pérez-Asurmendi P, García-Lapresta JL (2013) Collective transitivity in majorities based on difference in support. Fuzzy Sets Syst 216:3–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLean I, Urken AB (1995) Class social choice. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Meek BL (1975) A transferable voting system including intensity of preference. Math Sci Hum 50:23–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Morales JI (1797) Memoria Matemática sobre el Cálculo de la Opinion en las Elecciones. Imprenta Real, Madrid

    Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi H (1981) Approaches to collective decision making with fuzzy preference relations. Fuzzy Sets Syst 6:249–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi H (2008) Fuzzy social choice: a selective retrospect. Soft Comput 12:281–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen AK (1970) Collective choice and social welfare. Holden-Day, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanino T (1984) Fuzzy preference orderings in group decision making. Fuzzy Sets Syst 12:117–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tovey CA (1997) Probabilities of preferences and cycles with super majority rules. J Econ Theory 75:271–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zadeh LA (1971) Similarity relations and fuzzy orderings. Inform Sci 3(2):177–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to two anonymous reviewers, Ahmad Fliti, José Luis García-Lapresta, Bonifacio Llamazares, and Ana Pérez Espartero for their valuable suggestions and comments. We also thank participants at the 2014 Social Choice and Welfare Conference (Boston) and the 2015 European Conference on Operational Research (Glasgow) for helpful comments. This work is partially supported by the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness (Projects ECO2012-32178 and ECO2012-34202). Financial support by the National Agency for Research (ANR)—research program “Dynamic Matching and Interactions: Theory and Experiments” (DynaMITE)—is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mostapha Diss.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 18, 19, 20, 21, 22, 23, 24, 25, 26, 27, 28 and 29.

Table 18 Probabilities of transitive \(R_k\) for 0.5-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 19 Probabilities of transitive \(R_k\) for \(\min \)-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 20 Probabilities of transitive \(R_k\) for \({{\mathrm{am}}}\)-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 21 Probabilities of transitive \(R_k\) for \(\max \)-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 22 Probabilities of transitive \(P_k\) for 0.5-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 23 Probabilities of transitive \(P_k\) for \(\min \)-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 24 Probabilities of transitive \(P_k\) for \({{\mathrm{am}}}\)-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 25 Probabilities of transitive \(P_k\) for \(\max \)-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 26 Probabilities of triple-acyclic \(P_k\) for 0.5-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 27 Probabilities of triple-acyclic \(P_k\) for \(\min \)-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 28 Probabilities of triple-acyclic \(P_k\) for \({{\mathrm{am}}}\)-transitive reciprocal preference relations
Table 29 Probabilities of triple-acyclic \(P_k\) for \(\max \)-transitive reciprocal preference relations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Diss, M., Pérez-Asurmendi, P. Probabilities of Consistent Election Outcomes with Majorities Based on Difference in Support. Group Decis Negot 25, 967–994 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-015-9467-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-015-9467-1

Keywords

Navigation