Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Stability and Effectiveness of Climate Coalitions

A Comparative Analysis of Multiple Integrated Assessment Models

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We report results from a comparison of numerically calibrated game theoretic integrated assessment models that explore the stability and performance of international coalitions for climate change mitigation. We identify robust results concerning the incentives of different nations to commit themselves to a climate agreement and estimate the extent of greenhouse gas mitigation that can be achieved by stable agreements. We also assess the potential of transfers that redistribute the surplus of cooperation to foster the stability of climate coalitions. In contrast to much of the existing analytical game theoretical literature, we find substantial scope for self-enforcing climate coalitions in most models that close much of the abatement and welfare gap between complete absence of cooperation and full cooperation. This more positive message follows from the use of appropriate transfer schemes that are designed to counteract free riding incentives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a survey of this literature see Finus (2008), Eyckmans (2012) and Benchekroun and Long (2012).

  2. Most models implement Pareto-efficiency through maximization of the utilitarian sum of individual welfare per region. MICA computes Pareto-efficient strategies by solving a competitive equilibrium on international commodity markets with full internalization of the climate change externality.

  3. The strategy set in stage 2 depends on the specific features of the models. These range from choosing abatement directly to the indirect approach of choosing to invest in a broad variety of capital stocks (including energy and abatement technologies). See the appendix for details.

  4. This notion of cartel stability was first applied to international environmental agreements by Hoel (1992), Carraro and Siniscalco (1993), and Barrett (1994).

  5. We apply the procedure thus outlined for the models MICA, WITCH and RICE, for details see Kornek et al. (2014).

  6. To be precise, the pure rates of time preference are constant in RICE and MICA, but diminish in WITCH from an initial 3–2 % over the course of a century.

  7. Technically, the STACO model only considers benefits from abatement, and payoffs do not depend on the level of damages.

  8. Since marginal damages are not entirely flat in any of the models but STACO, this procedure is just an approximation of the decomposition of the cooperative carbon price but since the abatement of the OECD coalition is unambitious and leakage is small, the error is negligible.

  9. Specifically, we will refer to model regions EUR, EU, and OLDEURO as “Europe”.

  10. Some models use a weighted sum in the social welfare function, see model factsheets in the Appendix.

  11. In MICA, the largest share falls onto the rest-of-the-world (ROW) region, which includes several non-OECD countries.

  12. Model regions Middle East and North Africa (MENA), Non-EU Eastern Europe (TE), and Sub Saharan Africa (SSA).

  13. These are the most commonly used concepts for this set of models in previous studies. The analysis could be extended to include blocking power (or core stability) which, for the sake of brevity, we leave for future work.

  14. Technically, this is because the STACO model is characterized by superadditivity, which means that the total worth of a group of players involved in a merger does not decrease, see Eyckmans et al. (2013) for details.

  15. In two models, there is no single carbon price within the coalition (WITCH and RICE) because maximization of social welfare for the coalition balances marginal value of emissions in terms of utility but not monetary units. This is different in MICA (where international trade balances marginal utility of consumption) and CWS (which uses a linear utility function). In WITCH and RICE, we instead use the social cost of carbon for the conversion (computed as the marginal utility of carbon inside the coalition divided by the marginal utility of average per-capita consumption inside the coalition).

References

  • Altamirano-Cabrera J, Finus M (2006) Permit trading and stability of international climate agreements. J Appl Econ 9(1):19–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1994) Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxf Econ Pap 46:878–894

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (2001) International cooperation for sale. Eur Econ Rev 45(10):1835–1850

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H, Long N (2012) Collaborative environmental management: a review of the literature. Int Game Theory Rev 14(4):1240,002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosetti V, De Cian E (2013) A good opening: the key to make the most of unilateral climate action. Environ Resour Econ 55:44–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosetti V, Carraro C, Galeotti M, Massetti E, Tavoni M (2006) WITCH: a world induced technical change hybrid Energy J 27(Special Issue 2):13–38

  • Bosetti V, Carraro C, Massetti E, Tavoni M (eds) (2014) Climate change mitigation. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Technological Innovation And Adaptation, A New Perspective on Climate Policy

  • Bréchet T, Gerard F, Tulkens H (2011) Efficiency versus stability in climate coalitions: a conceptual and computational appraisal. Energy J 32(1):49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carraro C, Siniscalco D (1993) Strategies for the international protection of the environment. J Pub Econ 52(3):309–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carraro C, Eyckmans J, Finus M (2006) Optimal transfers and participation decisions in international environmental agreements. Rev Int Organ 1(4):379–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chander P, Tulkens H (1995) A core-theoretic solution for the design of cooperative agreements on transfrontier pollution. Int Tax Pub Finance 2:279–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont C, Gabszewicz JJ (1986) New developments in the analysis of market structures. Macmillan, New York, chap On the stability of collusion, pp 243–264

  • Dellink R, de Bruin K, Nagashima M, van Ierland EC, Urbina-Alonso Y, Weikard HP, Yu S (2015) STACO technical document 3: model description and calibration of STACO-3, WASS Working Paper 2015–11, Wageningen University

  • Eyckmans J (2012) Review of applications of game theory to global climate agreements. Rev Bus Econ Lit 57(2):122–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Eyckmans J, Finus M (2006) Coalition formation in a global warming game: how the design of protocols affects the success of environmental treaty-making. Nat Resour Model 19(3):323–358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eyckmans J, Finus M (2007) Measures to enhance the success of global climate treaties. Int Environ Agreem: Politics Law Econ 7(1):73–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eyckmans J, Tulkens H (2003) Simulating coalitionally stable burden sharing agreements for the climate change problem. Resour Energy Econ 25:299–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eyckmans J, Finus M, Mallozzi L (2013) A new class of welfare maximizing stable sharing rules for partition function form games, working paper

  • Fankhauser S (1995) Valuing climate change: the economics of the greenhouse. Routledge, London

  • Finus M (2008) Game theoretic research on the design of international environmental agreements: insights, critical remarks, and future challenges. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ 2:29–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finus M, Pintassilgo P (2013) The role of uncertainty and learning for the success of international climate agreements. J Pub Econ 103:29–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finus M, van Ierland E, Dellink R (2006) Stability of climate coalitions in a cartel formation game. Econ Gov 7:271–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuentes-Albero C, Rubio SJ (2010) Can international environmental cooperation be bought? Eur J Oper Res 202(1):255–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (1992) International environment conventions: the case of uniform reductions of emissions. Environ Resour Econ 2(2):141–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Karp L, Simon L (2013) Participation games and international environmental agreements: a non-parametric model. J Environ Econ Manag 65(2):326–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolstad C, Ulph A (2008) Learning and international environmental agreements. Clim Change 89:125–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolstad C, Ulph A (2011) Uncertainty, learning and heterogeneity in international environmental agreements. Environ Resour Econ 50:389–403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornek U, Steckel J, Edenhofer O, Lessmann K (2013) The climate rent curse: new challenges for burden sharing, presented at 20th annual conference of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 26–29 June 2013, Toulouse, France, available at http://www.webmeets.com/EAERE/2013/prog/viewpaper.asp?pid=757

  • Kornek U, Lessmann K, Tulkens H (2014) Transferable and non transferable utility implementations of coalitional stability in integrated assessment models, CORE Discussion Paper nb 35

  • Lessmann K, Edenhofer O (2011) Research cooperation and international standards in a model of coalition stability. Resour Energy Econ 33(1):36–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lessmann K, Marschinski R, Edenhofer O (2009) The effects of tariffs on coalition formation in a dynamic global warming game. Econ Model 26(3):641–649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luderer G, Pietzcker RC, Bertram C, Kriegler E, Meinshausen M, Edenhofer O (2013) Economic mitigation challenges: how further delay closes the door for achieving climate targets. Environ Res Lett 8(3):034033

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGinty M (2007) International environmental agreements among asymmetric nations. Oxf Econ Pap 59(1):45–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metz B, Davidson O, Bosch P, Dave R, Meyer L (eds) (2007) Contribution of working group III to the fourth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris J, Paltsev S, Reilly J (2008) Marginal abatement costs and marginal welfare costs for greenhouse gas emissions reductions: results from the EPPA model, MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change. Report 164, Cambridge, MIT

  • Nagashima M, Dellink R, Van Ierland E, Weikard HP (2009) Stability of international climate coalitions–a comparison of transfer schemes. Ecol Econ 68(5):1476–1487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagashima M, Weikard HP, de Bruin K, Dellink R (2011) International climate agreements under induced technological change. Metroeconomica 62(4):612–634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus W (2008) A question of balance: economic modelling of global warming. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD, Yang Z (1996) A regional dynamic general-equilibrium model of alternative climate-change strategies. Am Econ Rev 86(4):741–765

    Google Scholar 

  • Paltsev S (2010) Baseline projections for the EPPA-5 model, personal communication

  • Paltsev S, Reilly J, Jacoby HD, Eckaus RS, McFarland J, Sarofim M, Asadoorian M, Babiker M (2005) The MIT emissions prediction and policy analysis (EPPA) model: version 4, MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change. Report 125, Cambridge, MIT

  • Ramsey F (1928) A mathematical theory of saving. Econ J 38(152):543–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tol R (2009) The economic effects of climate change. J Econ Perspect 23(2):29–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weikard HP (2009) Cartel stability under an optimal sharing rule. Manch Sch 77(5):575–593

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weikard HP, Finus M, Altamirano-Cabrera J (2006) The impact of surplus sharing on the stability of international climate agreements. Oxf Econ Pap 58(2):209–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang Z (2008) Strategic bargaining and cooperation in greenhouse gas mitigations: an integrated assessment modeling approach. MIT Press, Cambridge

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank all participants of the two workshops that led to this model comparison (Potsdam 8–9th of February, 2012, and Venice, 24–25th of January, 2013), and two anonymus reviewers for their helpful comments. We also benefited from feedback to presentations of the manuscript at Grantham Institute, LSE, at IGIER, Bocconi, and at the EAERE2013 conference, which is gratefully acknowledged. Ingram Jackard contributed to the review of numerical coalition models an preparation of the initial workshop, and we are grateful to Patrick Doupe, who helped us improve our style and presentation. Kai Lessmann received funding from the German Federal Ministry for Education and Research (BMBF promotion references 01LA1121A). The research work of Bosetti and Emmerling was supported by the Italian Ministry of Education, University and Research and the Italian Ministry of Environment, Land and Sea under the GEMINA project. The research work of Nagashima was supported by Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science, Grant Number 23730265.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kai Lessmann.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 216 KB)

Appendix: Model Factsheets

Appendix: Model Factsheets

Model: MICA (Model of International Climate Agreements), PIK, Germany

Model description: Kornek et al. (2013)

Model concept

Solution method

Multi-region optimal growth model with climate externality and international trade

Competitive equilibrium, full internalization of climate change damage within the coalition; implemented as non-linear optimization problem solved with a modified Negishi algorithm

Welfare concept

Parametric specification

Discounted utilitarianism in each region, joint welfare maximization with constant Negishi weights for the coalition

Pure rate of time preference \(\rho = 3\)%, elasticity of marginal utility \(\eta = 1\)

Markets and Trade

Model anticipation

Consumption good

Perfect foresight

Number of region: 11

AFR     Sub-Saharan Africa without South Africa

CHN    China

EUR     EU-27

IND     India

JPN     Japan

LAM    All American countries except Canada and the United States

MEA    North Africa, Middle Eastern and Arab Gulf countries, resource exporting countries within the former Soviet Union, and Pakistan

OAS     South East Asia, North Korea, South Korea, Mongolia, Nepal, Afghanistan

ROW    Australia, Canada, New Zealand, South Africa and non-EU27 European states except Russia

RUS     Russia

USA     United States of America

Base year

Time horizon and step

2005

2005–2195, 10 years

Climate

Climate change

Greenhouse Gases: CO\(_2\)

Temperature response model

Carbon dioxide concentration (ppm)

Temperature change (\(^{\circ }\hbox {C}\))

Mitigation options

Climate impacts

Abatement cost function for CO\(_2\) based on mitigation cost information from the REMIND model (Luderer et al. 2013)

Region-specific quadratic damage function in temperature increase

Damage as [%] of GDP based on Fankhauser (1995) following Finus et al. (2006)

Land use

Resources considered

Model: STACO-3 (Stability of Coalitions), Wageningen University, The Netherlands

Model description: Nagashima et al. (2011), Dellink et al. (2015)

Model concept

Solution method

Combined game-theoretic and integrated assessment model with regional benefits (avoided damages) and abatement costs of greenhouse gas emissions

Partial agreement Nash equilibrium between signatories and singletons

Welfare concept: Discounted net present value of regional payoff in each region, joint payoff maximization within coalitions; no full welfare evaluation but the Keynes–Ramsey rule used for discounting payoffs is consistent with a logarithmic utility function.

Parametric specification: Pure rate of time preference \(\rho =1.5\)%; implicitly \(\eta =1\)

Markets and Trade

Model anticipation

Carbon Trade is modelled as transfers between coalition members

Perfect foresight

Number of region: 12

BRA    Brazil

CHN China

EUR EU and EFTA (EU-27, Iceland, Liechtenstein, Norway, Switzerland)

HIA     High-income Asia (Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, and Thailand)

IND     India

JPN Japan

MES    Middle Eastern countries

OHI     Other high income countries (including for example, Australia, Canada and New Zealand)

ROE     Rest of Europe

ROW    Rest of the world

RUS     Russia

USA     United States of America

Base year

Time horizon and step

2011

2011–2106, 5 years

Climate

Climate change

Greenhouse Gases: CO\(_2\), CH\(_4\), N\(_2\)O, PFCs, HFCs, SF\(_6\), based on EPPA-5 model to calibrate the regional GHGs BAU emission paths

CO\(_2\)-e concentration (ppm) Radiative Forcing (W/m\(^2\))Temperature change (\({^{\circ }\hbox {C}}\))

Mitigation options: Regional abatement cost functions for GHGs are based on regional cost parameters from the EPPA model (Morris et al. 2008)

Climate impacts: Benefits are calculated as the net present value of the stream of future avoided damages from a unit of abatement in the current period, taking regional GDP growth and inertia in the climate system into account (Nagashima et al. 2011). This function is calibrated to a simple climate module, based on the DICE model (Nordhaus 2008), but calibrated on the EPPA-5 model (Paltsev et al. 2005; Paltsev 2010). The linear global benefit function is based on estimates of climate damage by Tol (2009). Benefits are allocated across regions with a share for each region (Finus et al. 2006).

Land use

Resources considered

  1. Notes: Exogenous technological change (annual efficiency improvement in abatement costs) is considered to be \(0.5 - 2 \%\) per year (regionally differentiated)

Model: CWS (ClimNeg World Simulation model, Version 2.0), KU Leuven, Belgium

Model description: Bréchet et al. (2011)

Model concept

Solution method

Multi-region optimal growth model with climate externality, maximization of coalition welfare, internalization of climate externality for coalition members

Nash equilibrium of carbon emission game solved by tatonnement algorithm between coalition and non-members

Welfare concept

Parametric specification

Discounted utilitarianism in each region, coalition’s welfare maximization with equal welfare weights for all members

\(\rho = 1.5\)% (constant), \(\eta = 0\) (linear in consumption)

Markets and Trade

Model anticipation

no trade in goods, trade in carbon emission permits (optional)

Perfect foresight

Number of region: 6

USA:    United States of America

JAP:     Japan

EU:     South East Asia

China:   China

FSU:    Former Soviet Union

ROW:    Rest of the World

Base year

Time horizon and step

2000

2000–2310, 10 years

Climate

Climate change

Greenhouse Gases: CO\(_2\)

3-box model of carbon cycle (atmosphere, lower and upper ocean)

CO\(_{2}\)-e concentration (ppm)

Radiative Forcing (W/m\(^2\) )

Atmospheric and ocean temperature change (\(^{\circ }\hbox {C}\))

Mitigation options

Climate impacts

Exogenous emission efficiency improvement over time plus region-specific abatement cost functions (power functions, exponent 2.887)

Region-specific damage function, power function of atmospheric temperature change (exponent 3.0), damage as [%] of GDP

Land use

Resources considered

Model: WITCH (World Induced Technical Change Hybrid model, version 2012), FEEM, Italy

Model description: Bosetti et al. (2014)

Model concept

Solution method

Hybrid Optimal growth model, including a bottom-up energy sector and a simple climate model, embedded in a game theoretic setup

Regional growth models solved by non-linear optimization and game theoretic setup solved by tatonnement algorithm between coalitions and non-members (Nash equilibrium)

Welfare concept

Parametric specification

Discounted Utilitarianism, coalition’s welfare maximization with equal welfare weights for all members

\(\rho = 3\)% decreasing, \(\eta = 1\) (log of consumption)

Markets and Trade

Model anticipation

Oil

Perfect foresight

Number of region: 13

CAJAZ:     Canada, Japan, New Zeland

CHINA:     China, including Taiwan

EASIA:     South East Asia

INDIA:     India

KOSAU:     South Korea, South Africa, Australia

LACA:     Latin America, Mexico and Caribbean

MENA:     Middle East and North Africa

NEWEURO:   EU new countries, CHE, NOR oldeuro: EU old countries (EU-15)

SASIA:     South Asia

SSA:     Sub Saharan Africa

TE:     Non-EU Eastern Europe, including Russia

USA:     United States of America

Base year

Time horizon and step

2005

2005–2150, 5 years

Climate

Climate change

Greenhouse Gases:

3-box model of carbon cycle

CO\(_2\), CH\(_4\), N\(_2\)O, HFCs, CFCs, SFs

CO\(_2\)-e concentration (ppm)

Aerosols considered: yes

Radiative Forcing (W/m\(^2\) )

Temperature change (\(^{\circ }\hbox {C}\))

Mitigation options

Climate impacts

Abatement cost functions for non-CO2 GHGs

Region-specific damage function with linear and power function term with exponent 2.2 in the temperature increase Damage as [%] of GDP

Land use

 

Decarbonization options in the Energy system (Renewables, Nuclear, Biomass, CCS)

 

Land use

Resources considered

Emissions from land use change are considered

Coal, Oil, Gas, Uranium, Biomass

Model: RICE Regional Integrated model of Climate and the Economy, SUNY Binghampton, USA

Model description Yang (2008)

Model concept

Solution method

Multi-region Ramsey-type growth model with joint production of GHG emission that causes climate externality

the non-cooperative Nash equilibrium; cooperative solutions under various assumptions of incentive compatibilities; coalition solutions (called “hybrid” Nash equilibria in Yang (2008))

Welfare concept

Parametric specification

Discounted sum of regional utility functions.

Pure rate of time preference \(\rho =3\)%, elasticity of marginal utility \(\eta =1\)

Markets and Trade

Model anticipation

-

Perfect foresight

Number of region: 6

CHN    China

EEC     Eastern European countries and the former Soviet Union

EU     European Union

OHI     Other high-income countries

ROW    Rest of the world

USA     United States of America

Base year

Time horizon and step

2000

2000–2245 (5 years)

Climate

Climate change

CO\(_2\) emissions and other exogenously set GHG emissions

the Schneider box model

Mitigation options

Climate impacts

Mitigation cost functions based on Nordhaus and Yang (1996) and updated with Yang (2008) which contains updates provided by Nordhaus

Climate damage functions based on Nordhaus and Yang (1996) and updated with Yang (2008) which contains updates provided by Nordhaus

Land use

Resources considered

exogenously set

Availability of fossil fuel resources at global level has been checked implicitly

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lessmann, K., Kornek, U., Bosetti, V. et al. The Stability and Effectiveness of Climate Coalitions. Environ Resource Econ 62, 811–836 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-015-9886-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-015-9886-0

Keywords

Navigation