Skip to main content
Log in

Taxation and the quality of entrepreneurship

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the effect of taxation on entrepreneurship, investigating how taxes affect both the number of start-ups and their average quality. We show theoretically that even with risk neutral agents and no tax evasion progressive taxes can increase entrepreneurial entry, while reducing average firm quality. So called “success taxes” encourage start-ups with lower value business ideas by reducing the option value of pursuing better projects. This suggests that the most common measure used in the literature, the likelihood of entry into self-employment, may underestimate the adverse effect of taxation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There is a theoretical justification for this assumption. Entrepreneurship is innovative in nature, and can open up new markets and opportunities for other entrepreneurs. For this reason, and in contrast to other factors of production, a higher level of preexisting entrepreneurship does not necessarily diminish the marginal return for other entrepreneurs (Henrekson 2007).

  2. The results are qualitatively similar if we run the regressions with the entire sample available for each entrepreneurship measure.

References

  • Acs Z, Szerb L (2009) The Global Entrepreneurship Index (GEINDEX). Found Trends Entrep 5(5):341–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(2):323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ardagna S, Lusardi A (2010) Explaining international differences in entrepreneurship: the role of individual characteristics and regulatory constraints. In: Lerner J, Schoar A (eds) International differences in entrepreneurship

  • Autio E (2007) Global report on high-growth entrepreneurship. Global Entrepreneurship Monitor

  • Autio E, Levie J (2008) Does entrepreneurship matter? Types of entrepreneurship and economic growth. Front Entrep Res 28(16) Article 1

  • Bygrave W, Hay M, Lopez-Garcia P, Reynolds P et al (2001) The Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) model for economic growth: a study of venture capital in 19 nations. In: Bygrave WD (ed) Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research. Babson College, Wellesley

    Google Scholar 

  • Bickett I (2011) “A Better Way of Business”, video podcast, November 22 2011

  • Bruce D (2000) Effects of the United States tax system on transitions into self-employment. Labour Econ 7(5):545–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruce D, Gurley T (2004) Taxes and entrepreneurial entry: an empirical investigation using longitudinal tax return data. In: Proceedings of the 97th annual conference on taxation, National Tax Association, pp 336–343

  • Bruce D, Schuetze H (2004) Tax policy and entrepreneurship. Swedish Econ Policy Rev 11(2):235–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruce D, Deskins J (2012) Can state tax policies be used to promote entrepreneurial activity? Small Bus Econ 38(4):375–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cagetti M, De Nardi M (2006) Entrepreneurship, frictions, and wealth. J Polit Econ 114(5):835–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll R, Holtz-Eakin D, Rider M, Rosen HS (2000a) Entrepreneurs, income taxes, and investment. In: Joel BS (ed) Does Atlas shrug? The economic consequences of taxing the rich. Russell Sage Foundation, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Carroll R, Holtz-Eakin D, Rider M, Rosen HS (2000b) Income taxes and entrepreneurs’ use of labor. J Labor Econ 18(2):324–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll R, Holtz-Eakin D, Rider M, Rosen HS (2001) Personal income taxes and the growth of small firms. In: James P (ed) Tax policy and the economy, vol 15. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford C, Freedman J (2010) Small business taxation. In: Adam S, Besley T, Blundell R, Bond S, Chote R, Gammie M, Johnson P, Myles G, Poterba J, Mirrlees J (eds) Dimensions of tax design: the mirrlees review. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Cullen J, Gordon R (2007) Taxes and entrepreneurial risk-taking: theory and evidence for the US. J Public Econ 91(7):1479–1505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Pindyck R (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Domar ED, Musgrave RA (1944) Proportional income taxation and risk-taking. Q J Econ 58(3):388–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gentry WM, Hubbard RG (2000) Tax policy and entrepreneurial entry. Am Econ Rev 90(2):283–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gentry WM, Hubbard RG (2004) The effects of progressive income taxation on job turnover. J Public Econ 88(11):2301–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RH (1998) Can high personal tax rates encourage entrepreneurial activity? IMF Staff Papers. Int Monet Fund 45(1):49–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RH, MacKie-Mason J (1994) Tax distortions to the choice of organizational form. J Public Econ 55(2):279–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson M (2007) Entrepreneurship and institutions. Comp Labor Law Policy J 28(3):717–742

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson M, Sanandaji T (2011) Entrepreneurship and the theory of taxation. Small Bus Econ 37(2):167–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson M. Sanandaji T (2013) Billionaire entrepreneurs: a systematic analysis. IFN Working Paper 959

  • Hurst E, Pugsley BW (2011) Understanding small business heterogeneity. NBER Working Papers 17041

  • Kanniainen V, Panteghini P (2013) Tax neutrality: illusion or reality? The case of entrepreneurship. FinanzArchiv: Public Financ Anal 69(2):167–193

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur SM (1982) Entrepreneurial risk taking, inequality, and public policy: an application of inequality decomposition analysis to the general equilibrium effects of progressive taxation. J Polit Econ 90(1):1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan SN, Sensoy BA, Stromberg P (2009) Should investors bet on the jockey or the horse? Evidence from the evolution of firms from early business plans to public companies. J Financ 64(1):75–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kihlstrom RE, Laffont JJ (1979) A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation based on risk aversion. J Polit Econ 87(3):719–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner IM (1973) Competition and entrepreneurship. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Kneller R, McGowan D (2011) Tax policy and firm entry and exit dynamics: evidence from OECD Countries. University of Nottingham working paper

  • Knight FH (1921) Risk, uncertainty and profit. Houghton Mifflin Company, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerner J (2009) The boulevard of broken dreams: why public efforts to boost entrepreneurship and venture capital have failed-and what to do about it. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist L, Sargent TJ (1995) Welfare states and unemployment. Econ Theor 6(1):143–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE (1978) On the size distribution of business firms. Bell J Econ 9(2):508–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mooij R, Nicodème G (2008) Corporate tax policy and incorporation in the EU. Int Tax Public Finan 15(4):478–498

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (2004) Schumpeterian profits in the american economy: theory and measurement. Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers 1457, Yale University

  • Panteghini P (2007) Corporate taxation in a dynamic world. Springer, Berling

    Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides CA (1990) Equilibrium unemployment theory. Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Stenkula M (2012) Taxation and entrepreneurship in a welfare state. Small Bus Econ 39(1):77–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullman H (2007) Crain’s Chicago business, “Talking Management” series, February 2007

  • Xavier R, Kelley D, Kew J, Herrington M, Vorderwülbecke A (2013) Global Entrepreneurship Monitor 2012 global report. Global Entrepreneurship Monitor

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Henrik Horn, Lars Persson, Raaj Sah, the participants in the IFN Brown Bag seminar and two anonymous referees for valuable comments. All remaining errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrea Asoni.

Additional information

The views presented here are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of CRA or any CRA employee.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Existence and uniqueness of equilibrium

Given that both the RHS and the LHS of Eq. (6) are continuous functions of \(\theta ^{*}\), sufficient conditions for existence of an equilibrium are:

$$\begin{aligned} w&> \frac{\theta _{l}(1+\beta p)-\beta E(\theta )}{1-\beta (1-p)} \\ w&< \theta ^{h} \end{aligned}$$

These conditions describe a relationship between the market wage and the distribution of the quality of entrepreneurial projects. The second condition simply says that the best possible entrepreneurial idea must yield a return higher than the market wage. The first condition says that the wage rate should not be inferior to a quantity that depends on the distribution of entrepreneurial projects. It is positively related to the lowest entrepreneurial project and negatively related to the average entrepreneurial project. Intuitively if the lowest entrepreneurial project increases, then market wage should generally be higher. However if the lowest bound on the distribution increases the average value of entrepreneurial ideas also increases, counteracting the first effect. Generally the effect depends on the particular form of the distribution. To get a sense of how strict this requirement is consider the following. Since the thetas are defined over a positive interval we can normalize without loss of generality \(\theta _{l}=0.\) In this case the first condition simply says that the wage has to be greater than some negative number. Since the wage is non-negative by definition this is not a strict requirement.

Nothing in the structure of the problem ensures a unique solution to Eq. (6). Since the LHS of the equation is decreasing in \(\theta ^{*},\) a sufficient condition for uniqueness is:

$$\begin{aligned} F(\theta ^{*})\left[ 1+\frac{\theta ^{*}f(\theta ^{*})}{F(\theta ^{*})}\right] \le \frac{1+\beta p}{\beta } \end{aligned}$$

This condition clearly imposes some restrictions on the shape of the distribution function of thetas that depend on the value of the parameters \( \beta \) and \(p\).

In our problem multiplicity of equilibria arises from the fact that agents can follow several internally consistent decision rules. Having a decision rule over decision rules will eliminate the multiplicity problem. One such decision rule is the following:

$$\begin{aligned} \theta ^{*}=\max \{\theta \in [\theta _{l},\theta _{h}]:V^{s}(\theta )=V^{e}(\theta )\} \ \end{aligned}$$

This decision rule generates the highest utility (discounted profit). Suppose there is more than one solution to Eq. (6), so that different decision rules are available to the agent. Call these solutions \( \theta _{1}^{*},\theta _{2}^{*}\ \ldots \theta _{n}^{*}\) and let’s assume, without loss of generality, that \(\theta _{1}^{*}<\theta _{2}^{*}<\cdots <\theta _{n}^{*}\).

Notice that \(V^{e}(\theta ^{*})\) is an increasing function of \(\theta ^{*}\); it follows that \(V^{e}(\theta _{1}^{*})<V^{e}(\theta _{2}^{*})<\cdots <V^{e}(\theta _{n}^{*}).\) Moreover since \(\theta _{i}^{*}\) for \(i=1,\ldots ,n\) are defined as those points that equate the value of searching and the value of entrepreneurship, it has to be the case that \(V^{S}(\theta _{1}^{*})<V^{S}(\theta _{2}^{*})<\cdots <V^{S}(\theta _{n}^{*}).\)

Let’s define \(V^{e}(\theta |\theta _{i}^{*})\) and \(V^{s}(\theta |\theta _{i}^{*})\) as the value functions for the entrepreneur and the worker when the agent chooses the \(\theta _{i}^{*}\) as his decision rule. Then \(V_{i}(\theta _{i}^{*})=\max \{V^{e}(\theta |\theta _{i}^{*}),V^{s}(\theta |\theta _{i}^{*})\}\) is the value function for the agent when using decision rule \(\theta _{i}^{*}\).

Equation (4) implies that if \(\theta _{i}^{*}>\theta _{j}^{*} \) then \(V^{s}(\theta |\theta _{i}^{*})>V^{s}(\theta |\theta _{j}^{*});\) hence from Eq. (3) we see that \(V^{e}(\theta |\theta _{i}^{*})>V^{e}(\theta |\theta _{j}^{*})\) for every \(\theta .\) It follows that for every \(\theta ,\) \(V_{i}(\theta _{i}^{*})\ge V_{j}(\theta _{j}^{*})\) when \(\theta _{i}^{*}>\theta _{j}^{*}\). We conclude that the agent will choose the decision rule that will give him at least as much utility as the others. Notice however that different \( \theta ^{*}\) imply that the agent will choose to become an entrepreneur with different probabilities each period. In particular, the higher is \( \theta ^{*}\) the longer the wait to become an entrepreneur (and enjoy the higher income guaranteed by it). It is possible that an impatient agent will choose a lower \(\theta ^{*}\) in order to enjoy the income guaranteed by entrepreneurship sooner. We do not address this issue.

1.2 Entry costs

With entry costs we can re-write (2) as:

$$\begin{aligned} V^{e}(\theta )=\theta -E+\beta \left[ pV^{s}(\theta )+\left( 1-p\right) V^{e}(\theta )\right] \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where \(E\) represents the entry costs. Following the same logic used before we obtain that \(\theta ^{*}\) is the solution to the following equation:

$$\begin{aligned} w+\gamma \int _{\theta ^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}(\theta -E)dF(\theta )=\frac{\gamma }{\beta }(\theta ^{*}-E)\left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta ^{*}) \right] \end{aligned}$$

with \(\gamma =\frac{\beta }{1-\beta (1-p)}.\) Note that the derivative of \( \theta ^{*}\) with respect to \(E\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\theta ^{*}}{dE}=1-\frac{\beta (1-F(\theta ^{*}))}{1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta ^{*})} \end{aligned}$$

and with simple algebra one can prove that \(\frac{d\theta ^{*}}{dE}>0,\) for all \(\theta ^{*}\).

The inclusion of entry costs in the model increases the “reservation entrepreneurial idea.” The inclusion of entry costs in the model affects the rest of the formulas in this article in a similar fashion, changing the level at which in any of the previous cases it is optimal to start a firm. However the qualitative conclusion of the paper does not change: the effect of an increase in the top tax rate on the quality or quantity of entrepreneurship depends on the shape of the tax schedule, i.e. the relative position of \(w\), \(\theta ^{*}\) and \(\hat{\theta }\).

1.3 Proofs of propositions

1.3.1 Proof of Proposition 2

Proof

We can write (9) using the known result:

$$\begin{aligned} E(x)=\int _{a}^{b}xdF(x)=\int _{a}^{b}(1-F(x))dx-\left[ (1-F(b))b-(1-F(a))a \right] \end{aligned}$$

which in our case implies:

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}\theta dF(\theta )=\theta _{h}-\int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}F(\theta )d\theta -F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\theta _{\tau }^{*} \end{aligned}$$

Using this result, writing \(\theta _{\tau }^{*}=\theta _{\tau }^{*}(\tau _{w})\) and differentiating (9) with respect to \(\tau _{w}\) we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\theta _{\tau }^{*}}{d\tau _{w}}=\frac{-w(1-\beta (1-p))}{\left( 1-\tau _{\pi }\right) (1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*}))}<0 \end{aligned}$$

Analogously we can show that:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\theta _{\tau }^{*}}{d\tau _{\pi }}&= \frac{-\beta \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}\theta dF(\theta )+\theta _{\tau }^{*} \left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }{\left( 1-\tau _{\pi }\right) \left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }= \,\,\, \hbox {using } (9) \\&= \frac{\left[ 1-\beta (1-p)\right] \left( 1-\tau _{w}\right) w}{\left( 1-\tau _{\pi }\right) ^{2}\left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*}) \right] }>0 \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

1.3.2 Proof of Proposition 3

Proof

As before, using the following expressions for the expected values

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}\theta dF(\theta )&= \theta _{h}-\int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}F(\theta )d\theta -F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\theta _{\tau }^{*} \\ \int _{\hat{\theta }}^{\theta _{h}}\theta dF(\theta )&= \theta _{h}-\int _{ \hat{\theta }}^{\theta _{h}}F(\theta )d\theta -F(\hat{\theta })\hat{\theta } \end{aligned}$$

writing \(\theta _{\tau }^{*}=\theta _{\tau }^{*}(\tau )\) and differentiating (14) with respect to \(\tau \) we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\theta _{\tau }^{*}}{d\tau }=\frac{\beta \left[ 1-F(\hat{\theta }) \right] }{\left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }\left[ \hat{\theta }-E(\theta |\theta >\hat{\theta })\right] \le 0 \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

1.3.3 Analysis when the marginal entrepreneur’s income is in the top bracket

Case 1: \(\theta ^{*}>\hat{\theta }>w\)

In this case the equilibrium is defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} w+\gamma \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}\theta dF(\theta )-\tau \gamma \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}(\theta -\hat{\theta } )dF(\theta )=\frac{\theta _{\tau }^{*}-\tau (\theta _{\tau }^{*}- \hat{\theta })}{1-\beta (1-p)}\left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(16)

The effect of a top marginal tax rate increase in this case is summarized by the following proposition.

Proposition 4

With a progressive tax schedule when the marginal entrepreneur earns more than the top marginal tax rate bracket and more than the average worker, the effect of an increase in the top marginal tax rate on entrepreneurial activity is uncertain.

Proof

As before we can calculate the total derivative of (16) with respect to the tax rate

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\theta _{\tau }^{*}}{d\tau }&= \frac{\beta \left[ 1-F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }{\left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*}) \right] \left( 1-\tau \right) }\\&\times \left[ \hat{\theta }-E(\theta |\theta >\theta _{\tau }^{*})+\frac{\left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }{\beta \left[ 1-F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }(\hat{\theta }-\theta _{\tau }^{*}) \right] \end{aligned}$$

the sign of this derivative is not certain and depends on the relative position of \(\hat{\theta }\) and \(\theta _{\tau }^{*}\). We cannot determine the relative positions of \(\theta _{\tau }^{*}\) and \(\theta ^{*}\) either. \(\square \)

Case 2: \(\theta ^{*}>w>\hat{\theta }\)

We consider the case in which labor income is taxed. As in the previous section we consider the case in which the kink in the entrepreneurial value function is below the value of searching. The situation when it is above the equilibrium is exactly as in Case 1.

The value function for the entrepreneurs is still the one described in (13) while the value function for the worker becomes

$$\begin{aligned}&V_{\tau }^{s}(\theta )=w-\tau (w-\hat{w})+\beta V_{\tau }^{s}(\theta )F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\nonumber \\&\quad +\gamma pV^{s}(\theta )+\gamma \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}\theta dF(\theta )-\tau \gamma \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}(\theta -\hat{\theta })dF(\theta ) \end{aligned}$$
(17)

\(\theta _{\tau }^{*}\) is the solution to

$$\begin{aligned}&w-\tau (w-\hat{w})+\gamma \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}\theta dF(\theta )-\tau \gamma \int _{\theta _{\tau }^{*}}^{\theta _{h}}(\theta - \hat{\theta })dF(\theta )\nonumber \\&\quad =\frac{\theta _{\tau }^{*}-\tau (\theta _{\tau }^{*}-\hat{\theta })}{1-\beta (1-p)}\left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Again the effect of an increase in the top marginal tax rate is summarized by the following proposition.

Proposition 5

With a progressive tax schedule when the marginal entrepreneur earns more than the top marginal tax rate bracket but less than the average worker, the effect of an increase in the top marginal tax rate on entrepreneurial activity is uncertain.

Proof

Once again we can calculate the derivative of \(\theta _{\tau }^{*}\) with respect to \(\tau \) from (18):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\theta _{\tau }^{*}}{d\tau }&= \frac{\beta \left[ 1-F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }{\left[ 1+\beta p-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*}) \right] \left( 1-\tau \right) } \\&\times \left[ \hat{\theta }-E(\theta |\theta >\theta _{\tau }^{*})+\frac{\left[ 1-\beta F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }{\beta \left[ 1-F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }(\hat{\theta }-\theta _{\tau }^{*})-\frac{(w-\hat{w})}{\gamma \left[ 1-F(\theta _{\tau }^{*})\right] }\right] \end{aligned}$$

the sign of this derivative is not certain. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Asoni, A., Sanandaji, T. Taxation and the quality of entrepreneurship. J Econ 113, 101–123 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-013-0375-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-013-0375-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation